Ex Parte 6978253 et alDownload PDFBoard of Patent Appeals and InterferencesAug 24, 201290009444 (B.P.A.I. Aug. 24, 2012) Copy Citation UNITED STATES PATENT AND TRADEMARK OFFICE UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE United States Patent and Trademark Office Address: COMMISSIONER FOR PATENTS P.O. Box 1450 Alexandria, Virginia 22313-1450 www.uspto.gov APPLICATION NO. FILING DATE FIRST NAMED INVENTOR ATTORNEY DOCKET NO. CONFIRMATION NO. 90/009,444 04/01/2009 6978253 101443RX 3419 38834 7590 08/24/2012 WESTERMAN, HATTORI, DANIELS & ADRIAN, LLP 1250 CONNECTICUT AVENUE, NW SUITE 700 WASHINGTON, DC 20036 EXAMINER RIMELL, SAMUEL G ART UNIT PAPER NUMBER 3992 MAIL DATE DELIVERY MODE 08/24/2012 PAPER Please find below and/or attached an Office communication concerning this application or proceeding. The time period for reply, if any, is set in the attached communication. PTOL-90A (Rev. 04/07) UNITED STATES PATENT AND TRADEMARK OFFICE ____________ BEFORE THE BOARD OF PATENT APPEALS AND INTERFERENCES ____________ Ex parte PRICEPLAY, INC.1, Appellant and Patent Owner ____________ Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 Patent 6,978,253 B22 Technology Center 3900 ____________ Before KEVIN F. TURNER, STEPHEN C. SIU, and JONI Y. CHANG, Administrative Patent Judges. TURNER, Administrative Patent Judge. DECISION ON APPEAL Priceplay, Inc., Appellant, appeals under 35 U.S.C. §§ 134(b) and 306 from a final rejection of claims 1, 2, 9-15, 18, 20-23, and 30. We have jurisdiction under 35 U.S.C. §§ 134(b) and 306. We AFFIRM. 1 Priceplay, Inc. is the Patent Owner and the real party in interest (App. Br. 2). 2 Issued December 20, 2005, to Wayne W. Lin. Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 2 STATEMENT OF THE CASE3 This proceeding arose from a request for ex parte reexamination filed on behalf of multiple parties on April 1, 2009, of United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 (the '253 Patent), based on U.S. Patent Application 09/342,866, filed June 29, 1999. Appellant waived appearance at an oral hearing scheduled for this appeal on February 15, 2012. See Communication filed December 8, 2011. The '608 Patent was asserted in Performance Pricing, Inc. v. Google Inc., CA No. 2:07-cv-432 (E.D. Tex. 2007), where the court granted defendants summary judgment for non-infringement of the '253 Patent, with that summary judgment affirmed by the Federal Circuit on February 11, 2011 (App. Br. 3). CLAIMED INVENTION Appellant’s invention relates to systems and methods of doing business over a global communications network such as the Internet, where competition and/or entertainment are used to determine transaction prices between buyers and sellers (col. 1, ll. 8-13). Claims 1, 2, 9-15, 18, 20-23, and 30 are pending and subject to reexamination. Original claims 3-8, 16, 17, 19, 24-29, and 31-33 are not subject to reexamination. Claims 1, 2, 9-15, 18, 20-23, and 30 have been 3 Our decision will make reference to the Appellant’s Appeal Brief (“App. Br.,” filed April 11, 2011) and Reply Brief (“Reply Br.,” filed July 12, 2011), and the Examiner’s Answer (“Ans.,” mailed May 12, 2011). Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 3 rejected and are appealed (Reply Br. 2). We take independent claim 1 to be representative: 1. A method of doing business over a global communications network comprising the steps: communicating to a buyer via the global communications network, a description of a product; accepting a first request from the buyer to buy the product for a price to be determined within a price range, the first request indicating that the buyer is bound to purchase the product prior to the price being determined; accepting a second request from the buyer to allow the price to be determined based upon a performance of the buyer while participating in a Price-Determining-Activity (PDA); receiving data from the buyer over the global communications network, said data representing the performance of the buyer during the PDA; and determining the price of the product based at least partially upon the data received, said price being within the price range and scaled to the performance of the buyer. (App. Br. 32, Claims App’x.). PRIOR ART REJECTIONS The prior art references relied upon by the Examiner in rejecting the claims are: Rossides 5,620,182 Apr. 15, 1997 Walker 5,779,549 Jul. 14, 1998 E-Commerce That May Be Closer to Home: Key Is Safe Settlement of the Bill, Asahi Shimbum, Tokyo Morning Edition, Jun. 22, 1996, at 19 (English translation; hereinafter referred to as “Asahi”). Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 4 The Examiner maintained a rejection of the claims on the following bases: claims 1, 2, 9, 10, 12-15, 18, 20-23, and 30 under 35 U.S.C. § 103(a) as being unpatentable over Asahi and Rossides (Ans. 4-12); and claim 11 under 35 U.S.C. § 103(a) as being unpatentable over Asahi, Rossides, and Walker (Ans. 12-13). Appellant relies upon the following evidence in rebuttal to the Examiner’s rejection: Declaration of Wayne W. Lin, dated September 30, 2010 (App. Br.; Evidence Appx.)(“Lin Decl.”). ISSUES Appellant has asserted numerous arguments as to whether the Examiner erred in proffering the above-cited rejection, which we detail in the analysis section below. We have considered in this decision only those arguments that Appellant actually raised in the Briefs. Arguments which Appellant could have made but chose not to make in the Briefs are deemed to be waived. See 37 C.F.R. § 41.37(c)(1)(vii). The issues arising from the respective positions of Appellant and the Examiner, which we consider herein, are: Did the Examiner err in finding that Asahi and Rossides render the subject matter of claims 1, 2, 9, 10, 12-15, 18, 20-23, and 30 obvious? Did the Examiner err in finding that Asahi, Rossides, and Walker render the subject matter of claim 11 obvious? Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 5 FINDINGS OF FACT 1. Asahi describes a system which allows a user to play games of paper-rock-scissors to determine the price for a product (p. 3). In the example disclosed, the user selects a “CD radio cassette recorder,” and is provided with the “standard price [of] 22,000 yen” (p. 4). 2. Asahi further describes that upon winning of the games, the price can be “16,800 yen,” “13,800 yen” or an undetermined amount “?” (p. 4). The user indicated that the user won twice but lost on the third go (id.). 3. After the game play in Asahi, the user decides to place an order, and enters the type, number and expiration date to the user’s credit card (id.). 4. Rossides discloses an expected value payment method to reduce the expected per unit costs incurred in paying for a given amount of a commodity (Abs.). Examples are provides wherein pre- payment is made prior to a bet, committing the buyer to purchase, where the pre-payment influences the odds of winning (col. 5, l. 20 – col. 6, l. 55). PRINCIPLES OF LAW A finite number of solutions within the skill and understanding of ordinarily skilled artisans can be indicative of obviousness: Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 6 When there is a design need or market pressure to solve a problem and there are a finite number of identified, predictable solutions, a person of ordinary skill has good reason to pursue the known options within his or her technical grasp. If this leads to the anticipated success, it is likely the product not of innovation but of ordinary skill and common sense. KSR Int'l Co. v. Teleflex Inc., 550 U.S. 398, 421 (2007). Nonobviousness cannot be established by attacking the references individually when the rejection is predicated upon a combination of prior art disclosures. See In re Merck & Co. Inc., 800 F.2d 1091, 1097 (Fed. Cir. 1986). ANALYSIS With respect to the independent claims rejected, namely claims 1, 18, and 30, Appellant argues the limitations of claim 1, and provides that claims 18 and 30 “are rejected for basically the same reasons that claim 1 is rejected,” and disputes the rejection for the same reasons provided in relation to claim 1 (App. Br. 21-22). As such, we take claim 1 to be representative of the independent claims rejected. See 37 C.F.R. § 41.37(c)(1)(vii). Appellant argues that the Examiner has ignored the limitation in claim 1 of “accepting a first request from the buyer to buy the product for a price to be determined within a price range” (App. Br. 11). Appellant argues that in Asahi, the buyer decides whether to purchase a product after the price is determined (id.). The Examiner finds that Appellant’s argument confuses Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 7 making a request for a purchase and consummating a purchase (Ans. 14). We agree with the Examiner. Claim 1 recites, in part, “accepting a first request” to buy, not buying the product, per se. The request to buy can be received and processed without a purchase being completed. In Asahi, the indication of the product desired corresponds to the initial request (FF 1). While Appellant emphasizes that claim 1 requires that the buyer be bound to purchase the product for the price to be determined (Reply Br. 2), we agree with the Examiner (Ans. 5), that that aspect of claim 1 can be found in Rossides, and the rejection need not rely on Asahi as teaching all aspects of the claim step (Ans. 15). While Appellant is correct that no actual purchase occurs in Asahi until after the price is determined (Reply Br. 3), that is not what claim 1 requires. It is clear in Asahi that an initial request is made without the potential purchaser knowing the final price of the item (FF 2). We do not find the first portion of the cited claim step requires more. With respect to the binding of the purchaser, also recited in that claim step, the rejection references Rosssides, as discussed below. Appellant also argues that in Rossides, payment is required at a point in the transaction at which the price had already been determined (App. Br. 12). In addition, Appellant argues that in Rossides, if the better loses the bet, the better may not be bound to purchase the commodity and can simply forgo the bet payment, in contrast to claim 1 (App. Br. 13). The Examiner finds that Rossides in not relied upon in the rejection as teaching the first Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 8 portion of the accepting step, and that in Rossides, a user must make a pre- payment which is not refundable and binds the user to purchase (Ans. 15- 16). We agree with the Examiner. As discussed above, we find that Asahi discloses that a request is accepted prior to the final price of an item being known. As such, the fact that Rossides does not teach the same is not necessary to sustain the rejection. With respect to the better in Rossides forgoing the bet payment, we do not find that that implicates that the better is not bound in some way. Appellant acknowledges that “in the cited examples [of Rossides], the buyer is bound to the bet after the predetermined bet payment has been made based on a predetermined price” (Reply Br. 4-5). While that statement is made with respect to the timing and predetermination required in Rossides, it shows that Appellant acknowledges that Rossides acts to bind the better, contrary to the arguments raised in the Appeal Brief (App. Br. 13). As such, we do not determine that the Examiner erred in this disputed aspect of the rejection. Appellant also argues that the Examiner “improperly read out the phrase ‘within a price range’ from the limitation” (App. Br. 14), and that the price range limitation requires and “an upper and lower bound within which the price may vary” and is different than simply a price (App. Br. 15). Appellant argues that the prices specified in Asahi are merely individual prices and there is no discussion of upper or lower bounds (Reply Br. 6). The Examiner finds that Asahi discloses a price range, and we agree. Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 9 Asahi provides the user with a standard price and discounted prices based on wins at paper-rock-scissors (FF 1, 2). We find that one of ordinary skill in the art would have viewed these prices as falling within a price range even though they are individual prices. Additionally, even if the “The third time?,” in Asahi, “implies that the boundary is not known,” as alleged by Appellant (Reply Br. 6), we find that this still discloses a price range. If the final price was zero, that would still disclose a price range, given the standard price, and thus having an upper and a lower bound. As such, we do not determine that the Examiner erred in this disputed aspect of the rejection. Appellant also argues that “[n]one of the cited references teaches or suggests the desirability of the modification that the examiner has simply concluded is obvious” (App. Br. 15). To the extent Appellant seeks an explicit suggestion or motivation in the reference itself, this is no longer the law in view of the Supreme Court’s holding in KSR, 550 U.S. at 418. The Examiner has provided an articulated reasoning with rational underpinning for why a person with ordinary skill in the art would have combined Asahi and Rossides. Appellant also argues that one of ordinary skill in the art would not have been motivated to require payment prior to the initiation of the game because Asahi does not provide the buyer with a price range (App. Br. 16), but as discussed supra, we do not agree. Appellant also argues that the Examiner’s reasons to combine do not hold up, specifically 1) because Asahi already addresses cheating, 2) because payment is already assured in Asahi, Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 10 and 3) because Asahi does not mention odds of winning (App. Br. 17). We, however, agree with the Examiner finding 1) that the encoding in Asahi is directed to identification of a buyer and not the buyer gaming the system, i.e., cheating, 2) that Asahi does not forbid repeated play, which raises the issues addressed in the rejection, and 3) that Rossides addresses odds (FF 4) such that Asahi need not address the same for the combination to be motivated (Ans. 18-19). Appellant also argues that proposed modification of Asahi would render it unsatisfactory for its intended purpose, because in the timeframe of the instant invention, given the uncertainty about e-commerce, alluded to in Asahi, one of ordinary skill in the art would have intentionally avoided adopting a required up-front payment method (App. Br. 18). The Examiner responds that the apprehensions of a single buyer do not mean that the invention is incapable of working, or satisfying the technical requirements, and the modifications suggested in the rejection adds to the functionalities of Asahi which are already present (Ans. 19-20). We agree with the Examiner. While Asahi discusses the apprehensions apparent in that era, it is also clear that the user in Asahi places the order through the system (FF 3), such that this undercuts the argument that users in the relevant period would have not been willing to provide payment information upfront. Additionally, since the purpose of the system in Asahi is commerce, it would be difficult to imagine requiring users to provide information for purchase renders the Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 11 system unsatisfactory for its intended purposes. As such, we do not determine that the Examiner erred in this disputed aspect of the rejection. With respect to dependent claims 13 and 22, Appellant argues that Asahi does not determine the price, at least partially, on the participation of the buyer in an auction (App. Br. 19-21, 24-25), so that Asahi and Rossides, cannot render claims 13 and 22 obvious. The Examiner continues to find that “[o]ffering a product at a declining price constitutes an auction of that product,” and Asahi discloses precisely that (Ans. 20). We generally agree with the Examiner. While the definition of “auction” is broad, we do not find it to be inconsistent with the specification. As the Examiner points out (Ans. 20- 21), the Specification of the '253 Patent (column 4, line 39-41) discusses both auction and reverse auction models, and we concur that the recitation of “auction” in claims 13 and 22 would cover both models disclosed therein. In view of Asahi’s disclosure of offering a product for a declining price, we agree that this would have been viewed as a reverse auction by one of ordinary skill in the art. Additionally, while agree with Appellant that auction and reverse auction processes are different (App. Br. 20), that does not imply that the disclosure of one does not render the use of the other obvious. As such, we do not determine that the Examiner erred in the rejection of claims 13 and 22. With respect to dependent claims 15 and 23, Appellant argues that the “offer received from the buyer” recited in each claim refers to an offer of a Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 12 price and not the action of choosing a product, which does not affect price (App. Br. 21). However, we agree with the Examiner that claims 15 and 23 do not recite a price submitted by a buyer, only an offer (Ans. 21). The selection of a particular product in Asahi would certainly affect the price since different products would have different ranges of prices. As such, we do not determine that the Examiner erred in the rejection of claims 15 and 23. With respect to dependent claim 21, Appellant argues that the price in Asahi is not dependent at least partially upon a bid selected by the buyer, per claim 21, and is only dependent on the number of times the buyer wins at the game (App. Br. 23). The Examiner finds that the final price after the results of the game playing is a price offered, which is selected by the buyer (Ans. 21). We agree with the Examiner. Appellant’s argument is interesting in that earlier in the Brief, Appellant argues that the buyer is not bound to purchase the product in Asahi (App. Br. 11). Accepting that reading of Asahi, it seems clear that after the game playing, the buyer has the option to select the “final” bid or price and enter information to make the purchase, if desired. To that extent, we find that the buyer selects a bid and the price is dependent on that bid at least partially, or in this instance completely. As such, we do not determine that the Examiner erred in the rejection of claim 21. With respect to dependent claim 11, rejected over the combination of Asahi, Rossides, and Walker, Appellant argues that the combination does Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 13 not teach or suggest a price within a price range because Asahi and Rossides only provide a single price (App. Br. 26-27). We disagree with Appellant’s characterization, as discussed supra, and do not find this to be a deficiency of the rejections. In addition, Appellant argues that Walker provides that each winning buyer gets a different prize or product, whereas claim 11 requires that a second price for the same product is generated based on the competition of at least two buyers (App. Br. 27). However, Appellant has not indicated where Walker requires the prizes awarded to be different, and we do not find support for the same in Walker. Given the different amounts of discounting disclosed in Asahi (Ans. 13), it would have been obvious to provide different discounts based on the placement of players in the tournament, per the rejection of claim 11 (id.). As such, we do not determine that the Examiner erred in the rejection of claim 11. Appellant also addressed certain secondary considerations of non- obviousness said to run counter to the findings of obviousness (App. Br. 28- 30). Appellant cites that the instant patent has been licensed to Yahoo!, Microsoft, and others (App. Br. 28-29), with Dr. Lin offering corroborating testimony (Lin Decl. ¶ 7). However, as the Examiner points out, the existence of licenses has been alleged, but their nature and specifics have not been proffered (Ans. 22-23). We cannot determine whether the licenses were sought based on claimed elements of the '253 Patent, or due to unclaimed features or non-technical considerations. As such, we agree with Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 14 the Examiner that Appellant has failed to proffer a proper nexus between the alleged licensure and the merits of the invention. Appellant also argues that the claimed invention solves at least one long-felt, but unmet need that was specifically suggested, but not solved, by Rossides (App. Br. 29-30; Lin Decl. ¶ 6). Appellant argues that by binding the potential buyer and by scaling the price based on a price-determining activity, this provides an individualized and customized demand curve for purchasers that can be exploited, as discussed but not realized in Rossides (App. Br. 30). The Examiner finds that the questions raised in Rossides are not long-felt, but unmet, needs, and that Appellant has not provided persuasive evidence of actual long-felt, but unmet, needs (Ans. 23-24). We agree with the Examiner. As provided in Dr. Lin’s Declaration, the instant invention addresses “an economic dilemma Rossides intended to solve” (Lin Decl. ¶ 6). Without more, this does not demonstrate that such an economic dilemma was a long- felt, but unmet, need. Based on the evidence and argument provided, the questions raised in Rossides may not be of general concern in the art. In addition, given that Rossides stipulates that its methods provide “a poor partial solution” (FF R1), we cannot state that any need expressed in the questions presented is “unmet.” As such, we do not find the arguments and evidence sufficient to show resolution of a long-felt, but unmet, need sufficient to overcome the showing of obviousness of the claims so rejected. Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 15 Thus, the proffered evidence does not constitute the necessary showing by the preponderance of the evidence that these secondary considerations should overcome the obviousness findings made by the Examiner. CONCLUSION We conclude that the Examiner did not err in finding that 1) Asahi and Rossides render the subject matter of claims 1, 2, 9, 10, 12-15, 18, 20- 23, and 30 obvious, and 2) that Asahi, Rossides, and Walker render the subject matter of claim 11 obvious. DECISION We affirm the Examiner’s rejection of claims 1, 2, 9-15, 18, 20-23, and 30. Requests for extensions of time in this ex parte reexamination proceeding are governed by 37 C.F.R. § 1.550(c). See 37 C.F.R. § 41.50(f). AFFIRMED Appeal 2011-013687 Reexamination Control No. 90/009,444 United States Patent 6,978,253 B2 16 ack cc: FOR PATENT OWNER: WESTERMAN, HATTORI, DANIELS & ADRIAN, LLP 1250 CONNECTICUT AVENUE, NW SUITE 700 WASHINGTON DC 20036 FOR THE THIRD PARTY REQUESTORS: ROBERT A. SALTZBERG MORRISON & FOERSTER LLP 425 MARKET STREET SAN FRANSISCO, CA 94105 LAURA L. KOLB SIDLEY AUSTIN LLP ONE SOUTH DEARBORN STREET CHICAGO, IL 60603 EMILY C. O'BRIEN QUINN EMANUEL URQUHART OLIVER & HEDGES, LLP 50 CALIFORNIA STREET, 22ND FLOOR SAN FRANCISCO, CA 94111 Copy with citationCopy as parenthetical citation