From Casetext: Smarter Legal Research

Sugar Institute v. United States

U.S.
Mar 30, 1936
297 U.S. 553 (1936)

Summary

affirming district court's remedial decree requiring public dissemination of the information gathered

Summary of this case from Todd v. Exxon Corp.

Opinion

APPEAL FROM THE DISTRICT COURT OF THE UNITED STATES FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK.

No. 268.

Argued February 3, 4, 1936. Decided March 30, 1936.

1. The restrictions of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act are aimed against such restraints of interstate commerce as are unreasonable. P. 597. 2. The Act does not forbid cooperative adoption by competitors of reasonable means to protect their trade from injurious practices and to promote competition on a sound basis; and such legitimate cooperation is not limited to the removal of evils which are in themselves infractions of positive law. P. 598. 3. The mere fact that correction of abuses in a business by cooperative action of those competing in it may tend to stabilize the business, or to produce fairer price levels, does not stamp their action as unreasonable restraint of trade. P. 598. 4. But, concerted action which produces unreasonable restraint can not be justified by pointing to evils affecting the industry or to a laudable purpose to remove them. P. 599. 5. While the collection and dissemination of trade statistics are in themselves permissible and may be a useful adjunct of fair commerce, a combination to gather and supply information as part of a plan to impose unwarrantable restrictions on competition, as for example to curtail production and raise prices, is unlawful. P. 599. 6. In applying the Sherman Act, each case demands a close scrutiny of its own facts, and questions of reasonableness are necessarily questions of relation and degree. P. 600. 7. Fifteen companies, which refined nearly all of the imported raw cane sugar processed in this country and supplied from 70 to 80% of the refined sugar consumed in it, formed a trade association, called The Sugar Institute, ostensibly for the purpose of doing away with unfair merchandizing practices, especially the granting of secret concessions and rebates to customers, which had grown up in the trade. They agreed that all discriminations between customers should be abolished and, to that end, that each company should publicly announce in advance its prices, terms and conditions of sale and adhere to them strictly until it publicly changed them. They also agreed upon a number of supplementary restrictions (which are considered in detail in this opinion), among which were (a) restrictions on the employment of brokers and warehousemen ( infra, 587); (b) restrictions concerning transportation, absorption of freight charges, etc. ( infra, 589); (c) limitation of the number of consignment points at which sugar was placed for distribution to surrounding areas and limitation of ports of entry to be used ( infra, 591); (d) prohibition of long-term contracts and restriction of quantity discounts on sales to customers ( infra, 593); (e) withholding from the purchasing trade of part of the statistical information collected by the Institute for its members and not otherwise available ( infra, 596). Owing to the position of these refiners in the sugar industry, maintenance of competition between them was a matter of serious public concern; and, since refined sugar is a highly standardized product, that competition must relate mainly to prices, terms and conditions of sales. The strong tendency toward uniformity of price resulting from the uniformity of the commodity, made it the more important that such opportunities as existed for fair competition should not be impaired. Held: (1) The agreement and supporting requirements went beyond the removal of admitted abuses and imposed unreasonable restraints. P. 601. (2) The vice of the agreement was not in the mere open announcement in advance of prices and terms — a custom previously existing which had grown out of the special character of the industry and did not restrain competition — nor in the relaying of such announcements, but in the steps taken to secure undeviating adherence to the prices and terms announced, whereby opportunities for variation in the course of competition, however fair and appropriate, were cut off. P. 601. (3) In ending the restraint, the beneficial and curative agency of publicity should not be unnecessarily hampered; publicity of prices and terms should not be confined to closed transactions; if the requirement that there must be adherence to prices and terms openly announced in advance be abrogated and the restraints which followed that requirement be removed, the just interests of competition will be safeguarded and the trade will still be left with whatever advantage may be incidental to its established practice. P. 601. (4) The refiners should be enjoined from gathering and disseminating among themselves exclusively statistical information which is not readily, fully and fairly available to the purchasing and distributing trade, and in which that trade has a legitimate inter-business; but the command should not be so broad as to include information in relation to the affairs of refiners which may rightly be treated as having a confidential character and in which distributors and purchasers have no proper interest. P. ___. 15 F. Supp. 817, modified and affirmed.

APPEAL from a decree of injunction in a suit by the Government under the Anti-Trust Act. The bill named as defendants an incorporated trade association called The Sugar Institute, the fifteen sugar refining corporations composing it, and various individuals. The decree below did not dissolve the Institute, as was prayed, but permanently enjoined the defendants from engaging in forty-five stated activities found to be in restraint of competition in the sugar trade.

Mr. John C. Higgins, with whom Mr. Edward J. McGratty, Jr., was on the brief, for appellants.

The practice of selling only upon open prices and terms without secret discriminations among customers is essential to the functioning of that type of competition which is beneficial to the public interest. It has uniformly been approved by the courts. United States v. U.S. Steel Corp., 223 F. 55; 251 U.S. 417; Chicago Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231.

American Column Lumber Co. v. United States, 257 U.S. 377, and United States v. American Linseed Oil Co., 262 U.S. 371, distinguished.

The Linseed Oil Company case did not involve a condemnation of an open competition plan in the real sense of the term. It represented a flagrant example of a scheme of unfair competition masquerading under the name of open competition.

In the case at bar, the Sugar Institute was organized to abolish the system of arbitrary and secret rebates and concessions under which part of the buyers had been given unfair and discriminatory advantages over their competitors. And the abolition of these discriminations was accomplished by making all prices and terms open and public. There was no secret consultation or exchange of information among the sellers about the prices or offers to buyers. There was complete and immediate publicity of all prices and terms and other important trade information to all buyers as well as to sellers. There was no campaign or propaganda for decrease of production or increase of prices. There was no discussion of prices or production at all. The Sugar Institute is the complete antithesis of the Hardwood and Linseed associations in every essential particular, and the case at bar presents none of the elements upon which the Hardwood and Linseed decisions were based.

The decisions of this Court in Maple Flooring Assn. v. United States, 268 U.S. 563, and Cement Manufacturers Assn. v. United States, 268 U.S. 588, recognize both the economic desirability and the legality of concerted measures to protect and promote the type of open competition sought to be achieved by the appellants in the case at bar.

All of the practices of the Sugar Institute in connection with the gathering and dissemination of price and trade information are well within the limits of lawful activities as laid down in the Maple Flooring case. In fact, they stop far short of the activities there approved. Each member of the Institute has at all times determined his own selling price in free and open competition with every other member, without any Institute calculation or discussion to guide or influence his action.

The relaying by the Institute of the price change announcements of the members, after they have already been made public by the members in the same way in which they had always been made public before the Institute was organized, is clearly in line with the principle of publicity of market information approved in the Maple Flooring case. It merely gives wider and more accurate publicity to what has already been publicly announced. It has none of the qualities of private propaganda for increase of prices, or secret consultation about special offers to favored customers, which were condemned in the Hardwood and Linseed cases. It is the exact opposite of those furtive practices, and is the closest parallel which can be realized in an industry of this character to the competition of the Stock and Produce Exchanges, which is held up by economists and courts alike as the ideal of free and open competition. In the Cement Manufacturers case, this Court definitely upheld the right of competitors to cooperate for their own protection against imposition, misrepresentation and fraud, even though they thereby concertedly restrict a type of competition which they had long practiced and which was not shown to be in any way harmful to the public. This specific application of the sound policy of upholding restraints of competition which have a reasonable basis was also exemplified in the Chicago Board of Trade case, supra, where this Court sustained an express agreement of all the competitors in the market to eliminate completely a long-established type of competition, not because it involved imposition or fraud upon themselves or others, and not because it was shown to be harmful or destructive competition, but because it was shown not to be as wholesome and beneficial as the type of competition which was substituted for it by agreement of the competitors.

The principles declared by this Court in those cases were reaffirmed in Appalachian Coals, Inc. v. United States, 288 U.S. 344.

Section 2 of the Clayton Act condemns the type of secret discriminations that were practiced in the sugar industry before the Institute was formed; and the concert of action involved in the adoption and observance of this fundamental code provision represents the only effective way of giving practical effect to the express mandate and the underlying policy of that section. Van Camp Sons Co. v. American Can Co., 278 U.S. 245, 254; American Can Co. v. Ladoga Canning Co., 44 F.2d 763, cert. den., 282 U.S. 899; Standard Fashion Co. v. Magrane-Houston Co., 258 U.S. 346, 356-7.

The practice of selling only on publicly announced prices and terms, without secret discriminations in favor of particular purchasers, is the only practical means of protecting both sellers and buyers from widespread deception and fraud, which are an inevitable part of the practice of secret price discriminations.

The steps taken by appellants to give effect to the basic agreement that sugar should be sold only upon open prices and terms, without discrimination among customers, did not constitute an undue or unreasonable restraint of trade.

As for the price reporting system, the price reported to the Institute is a price which has already been publicly announced to the trade by the reporting member; the function of the institute is merely to relay and give further publicity to the price announcement; the Institute relays the announcement not merely to the competitors of the refiner making the announcement, but to the entire trade, including buyers as well as sellers, through the most widely used public channels of trade information; and no comment accompanied these relays and no price or production propaganda of any character was ever indulged in by the Institute, its officers or members.

It is submitted that no case ever decided by this Court affords any basis whatsoever for a contention that the mere reporting of already public price announcements to a central agency in the industry for the purpose of giving them wider publicity is in any respect unlawful.

The findings leave for consideration the naked question whether there is, in the concerted practice of announcing prices before sales, any such inherent tendency to restrain or suppress competition as to require that it be held unlawful under the Sherman Act. We submit that this practice, as carried on in the case at bar, in a trade like the sugar trade, promotes free and wholesome and economic competition, instead of suppressing or restraining it; and it is therefore clearly lawful.

It may be that, in some other industries, selling products which are not standardized, so that price competition cannot immediately express itself with full force when a competitor has announced his prices before sales, it might be argued that announcing the prices after sales would be preferable; but we can see no soundness in such an argument even then. In the Steel Company case, supra, where the company's practice was to "publicly announce its prices, adhere to them with all buyers alike, and to give timely notice of its purpose to change them," this Court approved the practice as a sound and wholesome one.

It may be also that when competitors agree that they will not reduce their prices without announcing the decline some considerable time before it becomes effective, there is present some element of restraint upon competition. But in the case at bar, as to price declines, no waiting time at all was called for by any rule, or observed in practice. Price declines were not only instantly effective, but it was the practice to make such declines effective on all business entered on the day of the decline, even when the decline had not been announced until late in the day, and this practice was approved by an Institute Code Interpretation. Furthermore, the refiners sometimes repriced all business entered for weeks before a price decline.

As to price advances, it is true that it was the practice of the refiners, approved by a recommendation of the Institute, to announce such advances by 3 o'clock of the day before the advance. But the prior announcement of price advances was not due to the Sugar Institute. It was a part of the sugar move system and had always been the practice in the industry.

It is obvious, of course, that the prior announcement of price advances is an advantage to the buyers, especially when it is practiced as in the sugar industry for the specific purpose of giving customers a reasonable time within which to place their orders for as large a supply of sugar as they want to buy at a present lower price before the advance becomes effective. This practice was no part of any scheme to restrain competition. On the contrary, as the trial court found, there was no consultation among the appellants, and frequently an announcement by one refiner of an advance would result in a series of announcements by others, ultimately leading to a decline. Often, too, the advance would be withdrawn, because one refiner would refrain from following the announcement. Except in a few instances, a decline announcement was followed by all.

This, we submit, is open competition at its best, and upon the state of facts here presented, there can be no reason whatsoever for holding such a price announcement practice unlawful.

The justification for the adoption and observance by the refiners of § 2 of the Code of Ethics, relating to quantity discounts, is based upon the special facts of the sugar refining industry, and upon the ground that in such an industry, subject to the special conditions and surrounding circumstances, quantity discounts inevitably amount to, and can only amount to, discriminatory and arbitrary price concessions. Their abolition by the action of the competitors is therefore a proper and necessary means of eliminating a destructive and uneconomic competitive method, and is justified as a method of giving effect to the Code condemnation of price discrimination between customers.

As found by the trial court, the discounts and rebates given before the formation of the Institute were given to some large customers but not to all; they bore no definite relation to the quantities purchased, and they were not openly available so that, in the language of the court in the American Can case, 44 F.2d 763, cert. den., 282 U.S. 899, "all customers could learn the amount of purchases necessary to secure the best prices." They were purely arbitrary in the sense that they resulted from secret bargaining in each transaction, and in no sense did they meet the requirement that all purchasers "were entitled to know the amount of purchases necessary to obtain the saving." It must always be remembered in construing the provisions of the Code of Ethics of the Institute that they were directed to practices prevailing in the sugar refining industry and not to a purely abstract situation. The condemnation of quantity discounts was aimed at the kind of discounts which had made their appearance in the sugar industry, and not at an orderly system of graded discounts corresponding to reductions in cost, which might fall within the proviso of § 2 of the Clayton Act.

As for the regulations affecting brokers and warehousemen, in view of the functions performed by the broker and the warehouseman in the marketing of refined sugar, it is clear that the prevention of price discriminations and departures from the policy of open prices publicly announced would be utterly impossible if the refiners were unable to rely upon the observance of that policy by the brokers and warehousemen employed by them and their competitors.

The action taken by the refiners (1) in refusing to deal with carriers by water who refused to announce openly their rates and terms or who violated their openly announced rates and terms by the granting of rebates or concessions, (2) in guarding against participation by buyers, brokers or warehousemen in rates paid by refiners on shipments of their own sugar by private charter, and (3) in refusing to deal with trucking concerns affiliated with buyers, brokers or warehousemen or trucking concerns unwilling to sign non-rebating agreements, was, it is submitted, clearly justified under the same principles as those justifying regulations affecting brokers and warehousemen. The measures taken were both appropriate and necessary to prevent violation by the refiners' own agents of the basic principle of open prices and terms without discrimination among customers.

Transiting and diversion, for the purpose and with the effect of defeating the refiners' openly announced freight applications, obviously involve a fraud upon the refiner if done without his consent; and, if consented to by the refiner, involve quite as clearly a violation of the basic principle of open prices and terms, without discrimination among customers.

Similarly, the recommendations made by the Institute and the action taken by the refiners with respect to such subjects as tolling contracts, used bags, private brands, long-term contracts, pool cars and cargoes, and the like, were, it is submitted, entirely proper and lawful as reasonably necessary and appropriate to give effect to the basic principle. In connection with each of these subjects, there existed opportunities for discriminatory practices, which, unless guarded against, would have nullified in large part the carrying out of the basic principle adopted by the refiners.

The activities of defendants designed to effect more economic methods of production and distribution did not constitute an undue or unreasonable restraint of trade.

That the statistical information which the Institute failed to make generally available to the purchasing trade was of no interest or value whatsoever to buyers, and that buyers were in no way prejudiced by their failure to receive such information, is clearly established by the evidence.

The elimination of unnecessary consignment points throughout the country constituted, in a sense, a "restraint" of competition. The type of competition thus restrained, however, was, as shown by a discussion of the facts, wasteful and uneconomic — productive of no real benefit to the purchasing trade.

The unnecessary multiplication of consignment points at a tremendous cost to the industry — a cost ultimately borne by the buying public — is not, we submit, the type of competition, beneficial to the public interest, which the Anti-Trust Laws were designed to foster and protect.

Messrs. Walter L. Rice and Angus D. MacLean, with whom Solicitor General Reed and Messrs. Charles H. Weston and Hammond E. Chaffetz were on the brief, for the United States.

The Institute's "open price" plan is an unreasonable restraint of trade.

In a free competitive market a seller may know what his competitors have charged in the past, but he does not know in advance what prices or terms they will grant in the future. He must anticipate that they may offer more liberal terms as well as lower prices, and he will therefore be alert to initiate better bargains himself. Under the "open price" plan, on the other hand, a seller may confidently wait until his competitors announce better bargains, because he knows that they will not "scoop in" a large volume of orders by being first to initiate attractive offers. They have in effect promised him that they will not grant new prices or terms without advance notice to him. The assurance to each refiner that no competitor would vary his prices without advance notice was sufficient to defer declines and increase prices without justification.

Advance announcement of harsher terms or increased prices, posted with the Institute and relayed by it to members, constituted in effect an invitation to follow the advance. Since the advance became effective at a future time, the refiner first making announcement would lose nothing if other refiners failed to follow. Of the 48 attempted "moves" during the Institute period, 38 resulted in price advances.

The Institute's "open price" plan entailed many collateral restraints upon fair competition. As concluded by the District Court, the requirement of open announcement in advance of sales "necessarily in and of itself ended any possibility of special terms when price negotiations were essential." For example, long-term contracts, which had great economic value, were thus eliminated. Likewise, tolling contracts, used bag allowances, the packing of private brands, pool shipments, private charters, etc., although well recognized mercantile practices, were branded by the Institute as "discriminatory" merely because they had to be negotiated privately.

Under the "open price" plan each individual buyer was at the mercy of a combination of refiners. A buyer seeking better prices or terms had to assume the impossible burden of tearing down the entire price structure. Expert buyers were reduced to mere "order clerks." When buyers become convinced that they cannot obtain even a momentary advantage over their competitors, and that there are no better bargains to be had, they quit negotiating for better bargains, and this defeats true competition. Any system which substitutes "mass bargaining" for individual bargaining unreasonably restrains trade, and particularly where restrictive rules of a trade association arm the sellers for the imagined "mass" encounter with weapons which the buyers do not have at their command.

This Court has condemned "open competition" where buyers agree to adhere to reported prices and terms unless more onerous ones are obtained or unless they notify their association of any deviations. United States v. American Linseed Oil Co., 262 U.S. 371. The Court condemned the system not because of its failure to prohibit price variations, but in spite of it. It rejected the plan because as a practical matter it took away competitors' freedom of action "by requiring each to reveal the intimate details of its affairs."

Where a trade association supplements the exchange of statistical information with propaganda designed to limit production or raise prices, its activities constitute an unreasonable restraint of trade. American Column Lumber Co. v. United States, 257 U.S. 377.

Such restraints are even more unreasonable under the Institute's program embracing 70% to 80% of the entire sugar industry. The Institute examined refiners' and distributors' records, and held more or less formal trials of refiners to determine Code violations.

In Maple Flooring Mfrs. Assn. v. United States, 268 U.S. 563, and Cement Mfrs. Protective Assn. v. United States, 268 U.S. 588, this Court merely approved the collection and wide-spread dissemination of prices in past transactions, where competitors "were left free to base individual initiative on full information of the essential elements of their business."

The exclusive selling agency involved in Appalachian Coals, Inc. v. United States, 288 U.S. 344, lacked the power to control prices in any market, and it was not shown that its purpose was to impair "fair competitive opportunities." Chicago Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, merely involved the regulation of trading hours and bidding on an open commodity exchange, where there is complete freedom of competition.

Appellants concede that immediate publicity given to the prices, terms and conditions in all closed transactions would have resulted in preventing secret concessions and unfair discriminations. The decree does not disturb the system of selling sugar on "moves," whereby refiners make public announcements of price advances and permit buyers to contract for their requirements for the next 30 days at the price prevailing before the advance. The decree enjoins concerted action in selling only upon or adhering to prices and terms announced in advance of sale or refraining from deviating from such announced prices and terms.

Appellants were not primarily interested in eliminating unfair discrimination. The restraints imposed indicate that they regarded as "discriminatory" almost any variation in the net cost of sugar to producers. Under the guise of eliminating unfair discriminations, they barred many legitimate competitive practices which permit buyers to effect economies or obtain advantages.

Although the District Court found that there was no direct agreement among defendants on basic prices or consultation with one another after an advance had been announced by one of them, it found agreement and collusion with reference to specific terms of sale. The Institute rebuked members and non-members for announcing terms, such as freight absorptions, which tended to break down the selling structure. It obtained a written apology from one member for announcing absorption of switching charges, and circulated the apology to members together with a statement in which the Institute acknowledged equal responsibility "in having failed to challenge the announcement." Announcements were sometimes made or prepared in Institute meetings.

Refiners concertedly refused to deal with brokers, jobbers or warehousemen affiliated with each other. Every person engaged directly or indirectly in more than one of such distributive functions was compelled to elect, practically over night, to continue in only one of such functions. The Enforcement Committee of the Institute investigated and "disqualified" brokers or jobbers found to be so affiliated. Honest and efficient warehousemen and brokers were blacklisted because of such affiliations, the refiners recognizing that the "innocent must suffer with the guilty." The Institute acted as "judge, jury and executioner all at once." The primary purpose was not to eliminate secret discriminations and frauds, but to prevent variations in the cost of sugar to purchasers. Customers affiliated with warehouses or brokers were disqualified because they derived a benefit from storage or brokerage which their competitors did not get.

The brokers' pledge required brokers to promise under oath that they would strictly adhere to Institute rules. Competitors may not act in concert to compel brokers and warehousemen, under penalty for violation, to refrain from giving rebates to purchasers.

This Court has consistently condemned concerted action to compel "third parties and strangers involuntarily not to engage in the course of trade except on conditions that the combination impose." Loewe v. Lawlor, 208 U.S. 274. See also: Eastern States Retail Lumber Dealers Assn. v. United States, 234 U.S. 600; United States v. First National Pictures, Inc., 282 U.S. 44; Paramount Famous Lasky Corp. v. United States, 282 U.S. 30; Binderup v. Pathe Exchange, 263 U.S. 291; Anderson v. Ship-Owners Assn., 272 U.S. 359.

Section 3(c) of the Institute's Code was a general agreement not to absorb freight, and to charge all-rail rates on all shipments except those which customers ordered in advance over differential routes. Several refiners took the position that the prohibition against absorbing freight arbitrarily decreased the volume of their shipments to certain states, and operated so as to "parcel out territory."

In 1929 all refiners announced delivered prices for important competitive areas along the Great Lakes and the Warrior River. The delivered prices included arbitrary freight applications. Customers were denied the privilege of purchasing f.o.b. refinery for shipment over waterways and other cheaper differential routes. Sugar could have been shipped to Cleveland, Green Bay and Chicago at 13¢, 20¢, and 23¢, respectively, under the delivered price freight applications. Concerted action in maintaining delivered prices is indicated by the Institute's policing activities, the assurances exacted from non-members to adhere to delivered prices, and the reasons given by members for refusing to sell f.o.b. refinery.

The requirement that water carriers openly announce their rates and terms, and the restraints upon private charters, pool shipments, transiting, diversion, trucking, and other transportation privileges, were designed to prevent a lowering of market prices at destination points.

Members eliminated consignment points wherever they were able to reach an agreement. Consigned stocks were valuable to the trade. Refiners sought to shift the cost of maintaining consigned stock ($2,500,000 to $2,900,000 per year) to distributors.

Long-term contracts (providing for delivery more than 30 days after date of contract) were concertedly eliminated because they enabled buyers to obtain sugar at prices lower than those prevailing on the date of delivery. They were mutually advantageous to buyers and sellers. The requirement that long-term contracts be announced in advance of negotiation eliminated them, because such contracts could not be arranged without private negotiation. The Institute exacted a promise from a large distributor to maintain refiners' prices and terms on sugar committed to him under long-term contracts signed before the Institute, for the purpose of preventing the sale of such sugar at prices lower than those prevailing.

The decree enjoins restraints upon discounts reflecting economies in direct or indirect costs. Quantity purchases result in savings in such items as delivery. Even if pre-Institute discounts were given because of savings in method of taking delivery rather than because of the quantity purchased, the injunction against restraints on quantity discounts is proper because the Government is entitled to "effective relief." Local 167 v. United States, 291 U.S. 293, 299.

Tolling contracts, whereby refiners accepted raw sugar and returned a proportionate amount of refined sugar, making a charge for service, were restrained for the very reason that they jeopardized the price structure. Tolling was outlawed only to the extent necessary to preserve uniform prices, the Institute permitting tolling for raw sugar producers on condition that they would sell the sugar in accordance with the Institute's Code. Members were concerned over "discrimination" between customers only to the extent that it represented lower prices.

The restraints upon credit terms, including the 4-payment plan, split billing, and cash discounts, illustrate the purpose and scope of appellants' activities.

The restraints upon price guarantee, resales, and sales of damaged sugar and frozen stocks were designed to prevent variations from announced prices and pressure to reduce the price level. The concerted requirement that buyers elect at the time of making contracts, without privilege of change, the prices and terms in cases where refiners had more than one price or different terms in different or the same territories, deprives buyers of a valuable option. The restraint cannot be justified on the mere ground that it is in conflict with appellants' theory of "open prices."

Substantial savings of 5 to 10¢ per bag could be made by customers re-using their own bags, without great expense to refiners. In prohibiting allowances on used bags, experiments in the use of bulk containers, and the packing of private brands, the Institute deliberately disregarded the public interest in effecting economies. It is immaterial that these privileges could be enjoyed by only a few customers or that the practices were not susceptible to open announcements.

The decree properly enjoined the gathering and dissemination of statistics on production, sales, deliveries, stocks, and volume of sugar moving over differential routes, without making such statistics available to buyers. Purchasers, who were given statistics only on total weekly production and deliveries, were placed at an unfair disadvantage with refiners who interchanged detailed statistics on individual production of each refiner and stocks and deliveries by States. Refiners knew competitive conditions in each area, whereas customers knew only the situation in the country as a whole.

By leave of Court, Messrs. Goldthwaite H. Dorr, Thurlow M. Gordon, Wilson Compton, and Rush C. Butler filed a brief on behalf of the Cotton Textile Institute, Inc., Window Glass Manufacturers' Assn., National Lumber Manufacturers Assn., and Consumers Goods Industries Committee, as amici curiae.


This suit was brought to dissolve The Sugar Institute, Inc., a trade association, and to restrain the sugar refining companies which composed it, and the individual defendants, from engaging in an alleged conspiracy in restraint of interstate and foreign commerce in violation of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act. 15 U.S.C. § 1. Final decree was entered, which, while it did not dissolve the Institute, permanently enjoined the defendants from engaging directly or indirectly in forty-five stated activities. Defendants bring a direct appeal to this Court under the Act of February 11, 1903, 15 U.S.C. § 29.

The record is unusually voluminous. The court rendered an exhaustive opinion and made detailed findings of fact (218 in number) with conclusions of law, describing and characterizing the transactions involved. Numerous assignments of error broadly challenge its rulings, and the case has been presented here in extended oral arguments and elaborate briefs. We shall attempt to deal only with the salient and controlling points of the controversy. These involve (1) the special characteristics of the sugar industry and the practices which obtained before the organization of The Sugar Institute, (2) the purposes for which the Institute was founded, (3) the agreement and practices of the members of the Institute, and (4) the application of the Anti-Trust Act and the provisions of the decree.

The court states: "The testimony is transcribed in over 10,000 typewritten pages; more than 900 exhibits covering many thousands of pages were introduced in evidence."

First. — The sugar industry and practices prior to the formation of The Sugar Institute. — Domestic refined sugar, beet sugar, and foreign and insular refined sugar, known in the trade as "off-shore" refined, constitute about 99 per cent. of the Nation's supply. The remainder, consisting of domestic cane sugar, refined particularly in Louisiana, does not appear to be an important factor in the national markets. The fifteen defendant companies, members of the Institute, refine practically all the imported raw sugar processed in this country. Their product is known as "domestic refined." Prior to the organization of the Institute in 1927, they provided more than 80 per cent. of the sugar consumed in the United States, and they have since supplied from 70 to 80 per cent. Their proportion of the supply is even greater in the New England and Middle Atlantic States, being more than 90 per cent., while in all but a few States their share is more than 55 per cent. Each of the refiners is engaged extensively in interstate commerce. Their refineries are in the vicinity of Boston, New York, Philadelphia, Baltimore, Savannah, New Orleans, Galveston and San Francisco. The raw cane sugar which they use is imported principally from Cuba and to some extent from the insular possessions.

Beet sugar for many years has been an important factor in the domestic market. It is produced and sold chiefly in the middle and far West, providing in some States over 75 per cent. of the supply, and it competes with other sugars in a number of Southern and Middle Atlantic States. Off-shore sugar is refined principally in Cuba and to some extent in the insular possessions. Its important trade areas have been the Middle, Atlantic and Southern States; in some States it constitutes from 25 to 40 per cent. of the total supply. Both beet sugar and off-shore sugar are sold at a small differential below defendants' sugar. The trial court found that there was no agreement between defendants and the beet sugar manufacturers, or with the off-shore interests, to maintain any differential.

The court found that the defendants' refined cane sugar "is a thoroughly standarized commodity in physical and chemical properties." In exceptional cases and localities, certain of the defendants had built up a preference for brand names "sufficient before and after the Institute was organized to enable such brands to command a higher price than the sugar of the other defendants in sales from sugar dealers to their trade." In sales by refiners to manufacturers of products containing sugar — about one-third of the sugar consumed — "price, not brand, was always the vital consideration." And in the other sales, "one refiner could not ordinarily, by virtue of preference for his brand, obtain a higher price except insofar as another refiner might be giving a lower price by secret concessions."

The court further found that the "basis prices," quoted by the several refiners in any particular trade area, "were generally uniform both before and after the Institute, because economically the defendants' sugar, save for exceptional instances was and is a thoroughly standardized product."

The "basis price" is the price quoted at so much per pound per one hundred pound bag of "fine granulated" or "granulated" sugar. Contracts are closed with reference to this price but the purchaser has the option at stipulated differentials to specify for delivery an assortment of grades and packages.

It is a fundamental and earnest contention of defendants that the occasion for the formation of the Institute was the existence of grossly unfair and uneconomical practices in the trade, and that a proper appraisal of the motives and transactions of defendants cannot be made without full appreciation of the sorry condition into which the industry had fallen.

During the years 1917 to 1919, when the industry was under governmental control, prices were fixed and all forms of concessions and rebates were forbidden. The court found that, perhaps as early as 1921 and increasingly thereafter, the practice developed on the part of some, but not all, refiners of giving secret concessions. There were five refiners who never indulged in that practice, but the others, called "unethical" refiners, did so to such an extent that at least 30 per cent. of all the sugar sold by the refiners in 1927 carried secret concessions of some kind. The need of secrecy was urgent, for as soon as it was known that a specific concession was granted it would be generally demanded. That concessions were widely granted was generally known in the trade, and while each refiner was able to find out in a general way the approximate prices and terms of his competitors, it was impossible to know with any degree of accuracy the actual prices and terms granted in the innumerable transactions. The court also found that various causes contributed to the development of these selling methods on the part of the unethical refiners, chief among which was an overcapacity since the war of at least 50 per cent. Other probable causes were the lack of statistical information as to amount of production, deliveries and stocks on hand, leading to over-production, the uncertainties prevailing in the market for raw sugar which made the refined sugar industry highly speculative, the fact that, since 1922, most sugar has been sold through brokers, and the standardization of defendants' products which made their sales almost entirely dependent upon prices, terms and conditions. The concessions granted were largely, although not entirely, arbitrary. They were given principally to large buyers, but no system was followed in that respect. Even though there may not have been extensive resort to misrepresentations, "defendants entertained genuine fears that purchasers were falsely representing prices which they said they could procure from competing sellers."

It appears that these five refiners accounted for 25.45 per cent. of all sugar produced by defendants; in 1931, for 28.54 per cent.

Consumption of sugar in the United States decreased in 1927. The public "slimness campaign" of that year had substantial effect in discouraging the use of sugar. Certain distributors refrained from pushing sales because they could not sell profitably, but others were aggressive and sugar was generally available. While certain smaller distributors suffered because of the advantage enjoyed by some larger ones, that advantage was attributable in the greatest measure to efficiency, and the larger distributors did not obtain monopolies. The court found that there was "no substantial evidence that the situation caused, or would cause, substantial injury to the `ethical' refiners as a class," although they may have been inconvenienced and probably believed that the sales methods of their competitors were harmful. The declining profits for the year 1927 were attributable at least in large part, the court found, to causes other than the secret concession system, such as the "slimness campaign," over-production and dumping.

But whatever question there may be as to particulars, the evidence and findings leave no doubt that the industry was in a demoralized state which called for remedial measures. The court summed up the facts in the following finding:

"29. The industry was characterized by highly unfair and otherwise uneconomic competitive conditions, arbitrary, secret rebates and concessions were extensively granted by the majority of the companies in most of the important market areas and the widespread knowledge of the market conditions necessary for intelligent, fair competition were lacking. The refiners were disturbed economically and morally over the then prevailing conditions. At least one refiner, American, was concerned about the possibility of liability under the Clayton Act because of the discriminations resulting from the various concessions."

The American Sugar Refining Company, which, in 1927, had 25.06 per cent. of all sugar produced by defendants.

Second. — The purposes for which the Institute was founded. — Defendants emphasize the nature of the proceedings taken in the formation of the Institute. The court found that the refiners held a series of meetings, beginning in the summer of 1927, for a discussion of conditions "with particular reference to undesirable practices and secret concessions." In September of that year, there were submitted to the Department of Justice a proposed certificate of incorporation and by-laws for a trade association, together with a number of suggestions respecting trade practices. A "Code of Ethics" was likewise submitted to the Department of Justice and discussed with its officials, with the result that some changes were made, and the Code as concertedly adopted in January, 1928, was substantially identical with that worked out when those discussions were held. The court found that "with the exception of two minor changes, the Code has retained its original form." It has been supplemented from time to time by "Interpretations," that is, rulings interpreting or amplifying the provisions of the Code. The Department of Justice made three investigations of the Institute in 1928, 1929 and 1930 and had complete access to the files of the Institute. As new issues of the "Code" and "Interpretations" were printed, copies were forwarded to the Department.

Defendants stress their dealings with the Department of Justice as evidence of their good faith and of the propriety and legality of their purposes. "The functionings of the Institute," they insist, "were always under the eye of the Department." The court, however, found that the Department "was not notified of various important steps taken by the Institute in connection with illegal restraints," nor was it notified "as to those activities charged by the Government and denied by defendants in this case." The Department did not conduct a comprehensive investigation of the restraints here involved until the end of 1930.

Defendants urge that the abolition of the vicious and discriminatory system of secret concessions, through the adoption of the principle of open prices publicly announced, without discrimination, was their dominant purpose in forming the Institute, and that other purposes were the supplying of accurate trade statistics, the elimination of wasteful practices, the creation of a credit bureau, and the institution of an advertising campaign. The court recognized the existence of these purposes in its finding:

"35. Among the purposes of the defendants in organizing the Institute were: (a) the selling of sugar on open, publicly announced prices, terms, and conditions; (b) the gathering of trade statistics not previously available; (c) the elimination of practices which they deemed wasteful; and (d) the institution of an advertising campaign to increase consumption. But these purposes were for the most part only incidental to defendants' actual dominant purposes in forming and operating under the Institute."

The "dominant purposes" were found to be as follows:

"36. I find that defendants' dominant purposes in organizing the Institute were: to create and maintain a uniform price structure, thereby eliminating and suppressing price competition among themselves and other competitors; to maintain relatively high prices for refined, as compared with contemporary prices of raw sugar; to improve their own financial position by limiting and suppressing numerous contract terms and conditions; and to make as certain as possible that no secret concessions should be granted. In their efforts to accomplish these purposes, defendants have ignored the interests of distributors and consumers of sugar."

Defendants charge that the finding as to the illegality of their dominant purposes was "wholly without foundation." They charge that the finding was built upon an "inherent suspicion" and not upon the evidence. The Government answers by pointing to the elaborate review of the evidence in the court's opinion and findings. We think that it is manifest that the finding as to dominant purposes was not based upon any assumption a priori, but was an inference of fact which the court drew from the facts it deemed to be established with respect to the scope of the agreement between the members of the Institute and the actual nature and effect of their concerted action. The court found that the defendants "in most of their activities" had "gone much further than was reasonably necessary to accomplish their professed aims of eliminating fraud, waste and secret, unfair or illegal discrimination." The pith of the matter is in the following finding:

"37. At the inception of the Institute, defendants adopted a general agreement ostensibly to abolish all discriminations between customers but which in general purpose and effect amounted to an agreement not to afford different treatment to different customers, regardless of the varying circumstances of particular transactions or classes of transactions and regardless of the varying situation of particular refiners, distributors or customers or classes thereof. Under the guise of performing the agreement, against discriminations, defendants limited and suppressed numerous important contract terms and conditions in the particulars herein set forth, chiefly for the purpose and with the effect of accomplishing the objectives described in finding 36."

We turn to the transactions from which the inference of purpose is drawn.

Third. — The agreement and practices of the members of the Institute. — The evidence consists of the "Code of Ethics" and "Interpretations," oral testimony, the minutes of the Institute, and correspondence. Eliminating charges not sustained, the findings of restraints of trade rest upon the basic agreement of the refiners to sell only upon prices and terms openly announced, and upon certain supplementary restrictions.

1. The "basic agreement." — The "Code of Ethics" provided as follows:

"All discriminations between customers should be abolished. To that end, sugar should be sold only upon open prices and terms publicly announced."

There was nothing new in the mere advance announcement of prices. The court found that prior to the Institute, "general price changes were listed on the Refiners' Bulletin Boards, and brokers, customers and news agencies were notified, and frequently, as a courtesy, competitors would be telephoned. Except for notifying the Institute, price changes during the post-Institute period have been announced in this way. . . . Before the Institute, general price changes, including general changes in the selling bases of the `unethical' refiners, were disseminated and became known to the entire trade very quickly."

These price announcements must be considered in the light of the trade practice known as "Moves." The great bulk of sugar, as the court found, "always was and is purchased on what is known in the trade as `Moves,' although very substantial quantities are sold from time to time apart from moves." A "move" takes place when the refiners make public announcements that at a fixed time they will advance their selling price to a named figure, either higher than the presently current selling price or higher than a reduced price which the announcements offer before the advance. Some period of grace was always allowed during which sugar could be bought at the price prevailing before the advance. And in order to obtain their sugar at the lower price, the trade, unless it was felt that the move occurred at too high a price, would then enter into contracts covering their needs for at least the next thirty days. Defendants point out that in actual practice the initial announcement might be made by any one of the refiners and that the move actually takes place only if all refiners follow a similar course. If any one fails to follow with a like announcement, the others must withdraw their advance, since sugar is a completely standardized commodity.

Under the system of the Institute, there was no obligation to give the Institute the first notice of a change in price. The open announcements to the trade were to be made in the customary manner and notified to the Institute, which would relay the announcements. Prior to the Institute, when an advance in price was announced, the period of grace allowed for purchasing at the old price was uncertain. Sometimes it was very short, a matter of hours; sometimes sugar buyers who did not learn of the move in time, sent their orders in too late to buy at the old price. By an "interpretation," the Institute recommended that the members "announce changes in price not later than three o'clock." In its earlier form, this hour was to be that "of the day before the changed price becomes effective." But these words were deleted in 1929, and thereafter the announced price advances could be made effective at once. In practice, however, price advances continued to be announced to become effective the following day or even later. The court found that the effect of the "Three o'clock Rule," in and of itself, "seems to have been advantageous to the trade in case of a price advance in that the uncertain period of grace has been replaced by a definite one."

The court further found that the refiners "did not consult with one another after an advance had been announced by one of them and that the grace period was not in fact used by them to persuade a reluctant member to follow the example set, despite the business necessity of withdrawing an advance unless it were followed by all." The court found "no agreement among defendants on basis prices in the sense of an agreement to adopt a certain basis price from time to time and to maintain it during any period. Frequently an announcement by one refiner of an advance would result in a series of announcements by others, ultimately leading to a decline. Often, too, the advance would be withdrawn because one refiner would refrain from following the announcement. Except in a few instances, a decline announcement was followed by all." "Data respecting price changes have been circulated by the Institute without comment" and there appear to have been no "price discussions" at Institute meetings.

There had been a practice in the trade called "Repricing," — of "making price declines retroactive to sales made at previous higher price." That occurred usually when a decline was announced late in the day and was applied to all of that day's business. The court found that during the first few months of the Institute, defendants attempted to prevent repricing, but the prohibition proved impracticable and was abandoned. By a ruling in November, 1928, it was provided that "the custom of the trade permits the customer the benefit of the refiner's lowest price during the day, that is, a contract entered into or sugar delivered in the morning may be repriced at any lower price announced during the day." The court in its finding on this point stated that the ruling was evidently intended to prevent repricing beyond the period stated and "must have had some effect in discouraging it." Defendants challenge this criticism in view of the fact also found that refiners occasionally have repriced beyond the stated period, a practice which defendants say "had never prevailed in the pre-Institute period," and defendants insist that what the Code actually did was "to insure that repricing should be done publicly, with the benefit extended to all customers alike, and not done secretly for the benefit only of the concessionaires."

The distinctive feature of the "basic agreement" was not the advance announcement of prices, or a concert to maintain any particular basis price for any period, but a requirement of adherence, without deviation, to the prices and terms publicly announced. Prior to the Institute, the list prices which many of the "unethical" refiners announced, "were merely nominal quotations and bore no relation to the actual `selling bases' at which their sugar was sold. . . . The selling price was the price at which they purported to sell; the secret concessions were from this basis." And, in the case of some of the "unethical" refiners, changes in selling bases were made from time to time without formal public announcement in advance. The Institute sought to prevent such departures. As defendants put it: "Having adopted the principle of open prices and terms, without discrimination among customers, as the means of remedying the evils of the secret concession system, the defendants lived up to the principle." The court found:

"40. Under the Institute, defendants agreed to sell, and in general did sell sugar only upon open prices, terms and conditions publicly announced in advance of sales, and they agreed to adhere and in general did adhere without deviation, to such prices, terms and conditions until they publicly announced changes."

It was because of the range and effect of this restriction, and the consequent deprivation of opportunity to make special arrangements, that the court found that the agreement and the course of action under it constituted an unreasonable restraint of trade. The court deemed it to be reasonably certain that "any unfair method of competition caused by the secret concession system" could have been prevented by "immediate publicity given to the prices, terms and conditions in all closed transactions," without an agreement to sell only on the basis "of open public announcement in advance of sales." A "purpose and effect" of that agreement, the court found, was to aid defendants in preventing and limiting "certain types of transactions in which private negotiations are essential." Its operation "tended in fact, as it naturally would tend, toward maintenance of price levels relatively high as compared with raws."

The court found that "the number of price changes for refined as compared to raw sugar" had been relatively less since the Institute than before. This was "too marked to be explained by the drop in raw prices." There was "a marked increase in margin and a substantial increase in profits despite a concededly large excess capacity." The relatively higher price level for the refined sugar, as compared with raw, was such "as to negate the prevalence of free competition." Factors "largely responsible" for this relative stability of prices "and for the maintenance of price levels regardless of supply and demand, observable since the Institute," were the dissemination among the refiners of statistical information, "while withholding it in large part from the buyers," and the steps taken by defendants "to eliminate the possibilities of price variations to distributors or ultimate purchasers at any given time and thereby to deprive them of the opportunity, by underselling, to disturb the price structure." Other factors were "the friendly cooperative spirit which the Institute brought to the Industry" and the assurance to each refiner that he need meet only the prices, terms and conditions announced by his competitors in advance of sales.

The court also took note of the fact that the Institute, in connection with practically all of its activities, had obtained a high degree of cooperation "with the Domestic Sugar Bureau," the trade association of the domestic beet sugar manufacturers. That association had its "code of ethics," substantially identical with that of the Institute. There was also cooperation with the "off-shore interests." But in neither case was there any agreement as to prices or price differentials.

Contending that the trial court fell into "fundamental error," defendants assert that the Institute made no change in the historic marketing system of the sugar industry. They say, first, that the code and its interpretations did not in terms call for price announcements in advance of sales. As to sales on "moves," they say that the code principle and price announcement interpretations "of course worked out in actual practice into sales only on prices and terms announced in advance of sales, because of the very nature and conditions of a sugar move." As to the "small day-to-day sales between moves," they say that while it was probably "the general understanding" that strict observance of the principle required public announcements of a lowered price or better terms before sale, there was no evidence as to the actual practice in that regard. They explain that the Institute continued to operate "under the move system" because it is "a natural growth essential to the economical conduct of the sugar business." The cost of raw sugar makes up about four-fifths of the cost of the refined sugar. Raw prices fluctuate widely from day to day and substantially control the price of refined. Wholesale and retail distributors sell on a narrow margin of five or ten cents a bag. They cannot afford to stock large supplies because of storage costs, dangers of deterioration and the hazardous nature of the business. But, on the other hand, distributors have to buy considerable quantities in order to take advantage of carload freight rates and handling costs. The result of all these forces is the system "of buying on moves every month or two." To this, both large and small dealers have adapted themselves. By reason of the general practice, they are all on an equal footing as to the periodic fluctuations in price. On each move they have laid in a supply for a month or more. Having bought their current supplies at the same general market level the distributors must "sell out their current supplies with due regard to that level in order to avoid crippling losses from an intervening decline." This, defendants say, is "one of the greatest economic advantages of the move system."

Defendants concede the correctness of the statement of the trial court that if immediate publicity had been given to prices and terms in all "closed transactions," competitive pressure would have been so great that the refiners "would either have had to abandon the discriminatory concessions or extend them to all." They concede that it is "publicity" that prevents such concessions and "not the sequence in time between the sale and the publicity." But they raise the fundamental objection that the proposal is not adaptable to the sugar industry. They say that in an industry which "has traditionally, and for good reason, sold its products on `moves,' through the mechanism of announcing price changes in advance of sales in order that buyers may have an opportunity to buy before the price rises, it is not helpful to suggest a system of announcing price changes after sales."

Defendants' argument on this point is a forcible one, but we need not follow it through in detail. For the question, as we have seen, is not really with respect to the practice of making price announcements in advance of sales, but as to defendants' requirement of adherence to such announcements without the deviations which open and fair competition might require or justify. The court below did not condemn mere open price announcements in advance of sales. The court was careful to say in its opinion that it found it "unnecessary to pass upon the legality of the use of the Institute" for relaying such announcements, "if each refiner entirely independently of the others voluntarily made his own announcements without obligation to adhere thereto."

Defendants also review at length the relative prices and profits in the periods before and during the Institute. They insist that it is unfair to include in the comparison the earnings for either 1927 or 1928, because each year was abnormal, and they contend that if a truly representative comparison of results were obtained by using the years 1925 and 1926 as the pre-Institute years, and those for 1929 and 1930 as the post-Institute years, it would appear that the increase in the later period of the net earnings of the refiners was less than one-half of one per cent. Accordingly they reach the conclusion that their activities did not actually restrain, or tend to restrain, effective competition.

But we are not left to inferences from trends of prices and profits. The "basic agreement" cannot be divorced from the steps taken to make it effective, and the requirements of the Institute must be viewed in the light of the particular opportunities which they cut off or curtailed. The crucial question — whether, in the ostensible effort to prevent unfair competition, the resources of fair competition have been impaired — is presented not abstractly but in connection with various concrete restrictions to which the decree below was addressed.

2. Supplementary restrictions. — The requirements and practices designed to support the basic agreement, and which the trial court condemned, relate to the employment of brokers and warehousemen, transportation, consignment points, long-term contracts, quantity discounts and other contract terms and conditions, and to the withholding of statistical information.

(a) Brokers and warehousemen. — Most of defendants' sales are negotiated through brokers who receive their commissions from the refiners. The court found that prior to the Institute, a broker and a warehouseman "were frequently one," and might also be "a merchant or other sugar user"; that concerns which thus combined distribution functions frequently performed a valuable service to the industry; that defendants required an election of but one of these activities and the complete cessation of each of the others; that defendants made and rigorously enforced an agreement that refiners should refuse to deal with a broker, warehouseman or customer who acted directly or indirectly for any of them, or for any other sugar interest, "in other than the one elected capacity"; that each refiner submitted to the Institute lists of its brokers and warehouses which were then circulated among the refiners, and those disqualified were dropped from the lists; that this policy was carried out in a harsh and arbitrary manner without regard to the effect upon third parties; that the commissions to be paid brokers were agreed upon, but there was no substantial evidence that the commissions were not fair, the object being to prevent a growing competition in bidding for brokers' services; that defendants agreed that they would not deal with any broker or warehouseman who did not sign a contract according to a form recommended by the Institute; that the warehouse agreement provided that if the warehouseman granted any concession or rebate, secret or otherwise, to any customer without granting it to all, an equal amount should be forfeited to the employing refiner; that the brokers' agreement prohibited concessions and imposed an obligation to uphold the Institute's code and its interpretations. This course of dealing, the court held, unreasonably restrained trade.

Defendants urge that the broker is the refiner's agent to sell to customers and the warehouseman is the refiner's agent for storage and delivery; that these agents act as a check on each other; that the refiners' concerted adoption of the principle against storing in customers' and brokers' warehouses was essential both to prevent discrimination among customers and to avoid impositions and frauds upon the refiners; that if the warehouseman is himself the purchaser of the sugar, the refiner is deprived of his independence and disinterestedness and the purchaser has control of the sugar with the power of withdrawing it at will and reporting that withdrawal at his pleasure; that similarly storage with brokers facilitated fraudulent practices, and that where the warehouseman and the broker were the same, neither was under any supervision and the broker-warehouseman could do practically what he pleased with the refiner's property and business.

To a considerable degree the court recognized the force of these contentions. The court found that a combination of distribution functions facilitated secret concessions, difficult of detection, and created opportunities for double dealing. But, despite this, it had been common for refiners, before the Institute, to employ brokers and warehousemen engaged in other distribution functions, and that such arrangements from the refiners' viewpoint were not infrequently entirely successful; and that concerns in substantial numbers, which combined distribution functions, maintained entire good faith in their dealings with the refiners. The court concluded that there was a definite possibility of lower prices to ultimate consumers as a result of combination of functions, because the increased income thus made possible, even apart from advantages obtained through secret concessions and fraudulent practices, gave opportunity "to outsell competitors who engage in only one occupation." The most important purpose of defendants, the court found, in compelling the separation of occupations was to aid in preserving "the uniformity of price structure," which would otherwise be threatened. The court deemed it reasonably certain that defendants could have secured adequate protection against illicit practices by means far less drastic, that is, through investigations, inspections, and publicity for which the Institute had unlimited resources.

The finding of purpose and of the adequacy of alternative measures is sharply contested. But, while the parties present their respective views as to the details of evidence, there is no room for doubt as to the nature and effect of the restrictions actually imposed through the Institute. The findings of the court as to agreement and practice are fully supported.

(b) Transportation. — The custom of the trade was to quote sugar f.o.b. refinery. Since the price was usually the same or varied but slightly, individual refiners sold in areas enjoying lower freight rates from other refineries by paying or absorbing part of the transportation charges. That is, the refiner added to the refinery price the amount of his "ruling freight basis" or "freight application," which was the amount the customer was to pay as distinguished from the actual cost of the transportation. The freight situation was complicated by the existence of differential routes, involving all-water or a combination of water and rail transportation. Traditionally in the industry, refiners' freight applications on sugar delivered at Great Lakes ports openly broke down during the season of open navigation to the Philadelphia lake and rail rate, and during 1926 and 1927 the freight application on sugar sold in the Warrior River area (Alabama, Tennessee, Kentucky and parts of Indiana) had openly broken down to New Orleans barge rates, regardless of the way in which the sugar actually moved. The areas affected by these breakdowns were of vital importance, as competition there was especially keen.

In the effort to prevent the "sale" of transportation below "cost," the Code of Ethics, paragraph 3(c), condemned "The use of differential rates on consignments, or otherwise than on direct shipments over differential routes at customers' request." This policy was amplified by an interpretation. The trial court found that but "slight effort was made to enforce Code 3(c) after the summer of 1928," that it "was abandoned at least by the fall of 1929 and probably much earlier," and that the code interpretation was finally rescinded in September, 1930.

The court found that the transportation problems in the Great Lakes and Warrior River areas were finally solved by a system of delivered prices, with denial of the privilege of purchasing f. o.b. refinery. The court did not find that there was an agreement in introducing the delivered prices, but did find that defendants "agreed to maintain and concertedly maintained the system of delivered prices" in both the areas above mentioned; also that through the Institute defendants "concertedly policed delivered prices and investigated alleged departures therefrom"; and that these prices were "patently unreasonable." Defendants vigorously deny that delivered prices were either introduced or maintained through any concert of action. They submit that the evidence not only does not warrant that finding, but shows affirmatively that delivered prices were introduced independently by individual refiners and resulted solely from unrestrained competition.

As the court said in its opinion, the controversy was chiefly about what defendants had actually done during the Institute period, and the facts were frequently "bitterly disputed." We need not discuss the rival contentions. The court found that defendants' "adoption of Code 3(c), their actions pursuant thereto, and their concerted maintenance of delivered prices constituted undue and unreasonable restraint of trade." Defendants have waived their assignment of error as to this finding in order to reduce the issues presented on this appeal. And defendants have also waived their assignments of error as to the provisions in the decree enjoining concerted action in "Determining transportation charges or freight applications to be collected from customers, or limiting freight absorptions" and in "Selling only on delivered prices or on any system of delivered prices, including zone prices, or refusing to sell f.o.b. refinery."

Questions are presented with respect to miscellaneous "transportation activities." They relate to defendants' agreement to prevent transiting and diversion by customers when these would defeat freight applications; to concerted action in obtaining an agreement from transportation companies operating on the New York State Barge Canal that they would carry sugar only on the basis of openly announced rates and terms from which they would not deviate without open announcement; to recommendations of the Institute, concertedly observed, that none of the members should ship sugar on his own account by private charter except when the charter was arranged directly between refiner and carrier and refiner was satisfied that no broker, buyer or warehouseman was participating in the rate, and that the terms of every such private charter should be submitted to the scrutiny of the executive secretary of the Institute; to defendants' concerted refusal to participate in pool shipments, with sugar shipped on their own account, in order to aid customers in making up the required minima for cargo or carload rates; and to defendants' agreement "to use only trucking concerns not affiliated with any buyer, broker, or warehouse and then only under non-rebating contracts." The court found that defendants' action went further than was necessary to prevent secret rebating and amounted to unreasonable restraints. We see no reason for disturbing the findings on these subjects.

(c) Consignment points. — Prior to 1925, the refiners maintained, on their respective accounts, stocks at a few strategic points from which sugar was distributed to the surrounding areas. During the period 1925 to 1927, refiners placed stocks at numerous points solely for the local trade. Defendants regarded this increase as an outstanding evil and made a concerted effort to bring about reductions. To this end the Institute obtained the cooperation of the Domestic Sugar Bureau and other non-members. In recommending consignment points in the South, ports of entry like reconsignment points were separately classified, and Wilmington, North Carolina, was eliminated.

Defendants insist that the expense involved in maintaining an excessive number of consignment points was an economic waste without any substantial compensating advantage to the consuming public, and that the effort at reduction was a legitimate function of the Institute. The economic questions were fully considered by the trial court which found that the refiners' consignment service "was valuable and beneficial to substantial elements in the trade"; that limitation of ports of entry was more serious than elimination of ordinary consignment points insofar as it shut a competitor out of a particular territory; that while the cost of increased consignment points might well be reflected in a higher general basis price, there was no assurance that the savings through some reductions would be passed on to consumers generally; that the result in either case was "largely speculative"; that communities eliminated as consignment points "suffered as against neighboring ones" because of the advantage accruing to the latter; and that there were also eliminated from distributing agencies one type of jobber called the "desk jobber" who was able to do business without any stock of his own. In summary, the court found that defendants' "concerted conduct with respect to elimination and reduction of consignment points, reconsignment points and ports of entry" unreasonably restrained trade. The controlling facts are established, and the question again is one of justification.

(d) Various contract terms and conditions. — One question relates to "long term contracts," that is, those permitting the buyer to take delivery more than thirty days after date. Prior to the World War, thirty day contracts were customary for all except manufacturers who were granted sixty days. While there was no definite practice after the war, long term contracts were not infrequent. They were granted by California refiners to Pacific Coast canners. The court found that long term contracts had "a real economic value to refiner and to consumer"; that some of them tend to bring about greater evenness of production through the year, thus effectuating economies and enabling manufacturers promptly to know the cost of this element of their finished products.

Defendants contest the finding of the court that they engaged in concerted action "in prohibiting all long term contracts," and assert that "they never have had and do not now have any desire to prohibit them." Hence, they add, the court's injunction against such action "does not disturb them." But they object to the finding that concerted action in insisting upon open announcement in advance of entering into such contracts was without justification. This, as defendants say, is but a condemnation of a particular application of their basic principle that sugar should be sold only upon open prices and terms without discrimination. In the view of the trial court, this application is an illustration of its point that an obligation to adhere to such advance announcements "would tend to prevent many entirely fair contracts." Of similar import is the finding that defendants were not justified in acting concertedly to determine whether and to what extent "the rigid enforcement of the thirty day contract" should be relaxed.

Another question which has received extended consideration is that of "quantity discounts." Prior to the Institute, there was no systematic practice in this respect. The majority of discounts were given to the large buyer but they were often granted to the smaller buyer as well, and the amount of the discount "bore little relation to the amount of the purchases or the method of taking delivery." This, the court found, was the natural result of the "secret concession system" which had prevailed. Carrying out its policy as to discriminations, the Institute condemned "as unbusiness-like, uneconomic and unsound, concessions made to purchasers on the basis of quantity purchased." The court found that this agreement and the practice under it prohibited not only "unsystematic and secret quantity discounts," but also discounts "systematically graded according to quantity." The court examined defendants' contention that quantity discounts would effect no economies. If, said the court, the facts were as defendants insisted, the question would arise whether such a concerted restraint was reasonable. But the court considered the actual facts to be "entirely inconsistent with defendants' position." As to direct costs, the court found that the refiners got no discount for quantity purchases of raws, which constitute about 80 per cent. of the cost of refined; that quantity sales effected no appreciable direct savings in manufacturing costs and no savings in brokerage; but that in sales to those who could take deliveries in carload lots direct from the refinery, there were substantial savings "in delivery, storage, bookkeeping and other incidental expenses." And as to indirect costs, the court found that sales which distribute production more evenly through the year effect substantial savings to the refiners and that the demand for sugar is elastic, so that encouragement of large sales through quantity discounts might reasonably be expected to build up total production and thus effect economies. Also that a quantity discount to wholesalers selling to manufacturers as well as to manufacturers buying directly from refiners, might well result in a substantial increase in sugar consumption.

Defendants contest these economic conclusions. But we are not convinced that the findings are contrary to the evidence. Moreover, the limited provision of the decree should be regarded. In this relation, the decree enjoins defendants from concerted action in "Preventing, restraining or refusing to grant quantity or other discounts where such discounts reflect, effect, or result in economies to refiners either in direct or indirect costs."

With a single exception, defendants do not ask the court to review the findings with respect to credit arrangements known as "the four payment plan," "split billing" and "cash discount"; or as to "price guarantee" and "second hand sugar or resales." They say that in each case questions of fact alone are raised and they disclaim having taken, or having any desire to take, any action with respect to these subjects which is enjoined by the decree. The exception refers to the practice of "requiring buyers to elect and specify at the time of entering contract, without privilege of change, the prices and/or terms in cases where the refiner had more than one price or different terms in different or the same territories." This restriction is defended as a necessary corollary of the principle of open prices and terms without discrimination, and the question is as to the legality of the restraint in the application of that principle.

Other questions concern practices in relation to "damaged sugar and frozen stocks," "tolling," "used bag allowances," and "private brands." The court found that the restraints imposed in these matters were unreasonable. They appear to be of minor importance and we think it unnecessary to state the particular facts.

(e) Statistical information. — Some statistical information collected by the Institute was supplied only to its members; some was supplied as well to representatives of offshore refiners. The data disseminated by the Institute to the purchasing trade consisted of weekly statistics as to the total melt (production) and total deliveries, and monthly statistics of total deliveries, of all sugar, divided so as to show the amount of domestic cane, imported cane, and beet sugar delivered during the period. These statistics were widely distributed through news agencies, banks and brokers. The total refined stocks on hand could be computed by subtracting from the total melt of each week the total deliveries. During recent years when refined stocks were greatly increasing, defendants continued to supply to the trade weekly statistics on melt and deliveries from which the trade could readily calculate the increase. Data as to the capacity of the several refiners were available to the public in substantially similar form to that obtained by the Institute. It also appeared that in May, 1931, after the present suit was begun, statistics were released to the trade showing the total consumption of cane, beet, foreign and insular refined sugar by States, for the years 1928, 1929 and 1930, together with figures showing the per capita consumption of each State during the same years.

The trial court found that none of the other statistics supplied to members or offshore refiners were available except through the Institute and none were supplied or available to the trade. What the court considered to be "vital data" relating to production and deliveries of individual refiners, to deliveries by States, to deliveries by States by all the important differential routes, to consigned and in-transit stocks for the several States, "which would have illuminated the situation in the several trade areas where the competitive set-ups differed widely," were withheld from purchasers. The court concluded that, by collecting and circulating only among themselves that information, defendants obtained an unfair advantage with respect to purchasers and effected an unreasonable restraint.

The court took the view that the statistics relating to total production, total deliveries, and calculable stocks, which defendants did make available, could have had only limited significance for the individual purchaser and were even likely to mislead him. Such information reflected only the general situation for the country as a whole and for all refiners. Defendants challenge this criticism and emphasize the value of the information they gave. And with respect to the statistics not disseminated, they say that it did not appear how buyers were prejudiced and that the sole reason that the information was not published was "because the refiners had no reason to believe that the buyers wanted it." We cannot say, however, that the finding of the trial court, in connection with its exhaustive examination of conditions in the trade, is without adequate support. We shall presently consider the criticism from a legal standpoint of the breadth of the provision in the decree relating to the duty of dissemination.

Fourth. — The application of the Anti-Trust Act and the provisions of the decree. — The restrictions imposed by the Sherman Act are not mechanical or artificial. We have repeatedly said that they set up the essential standard of reasonableness. Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1; United States v. American Tobacco Co., 221 U.S. 106. They are aimed at contracts and combinations which "by reason of intent or the inherent nature of the contemplated acts, prejudice the public interests by unduly restraining competition or unduly obstructing the course of trade." Nash v. United States, 229 U.S. 373, 376; United States v. Linseed Oil Co., 262 U.S. 371, 388, 389. Designed to frustrate unreasonable restraints, they do not prevent the adoption of reasonable means to protect interstate commerce from destructive or injurious practices and to promote competition upon a sound basis. Voluntary action to end abuses and to foster fair competitive opportunities in the public interest may be more effective than legal processes. And cooperative endeavor may appropriately have wider objectives than merely the removal of evils which are infractions of positive law. Nor does the fact that the correction of abuses may tend to stabilize a business, or to produce fairer price levels, require that abuses should go uncorrected or that an effort to correct them should for that reason alone be stamped as an unreasonable restraint of trade. Accordingly we have held that a cooperative enterprise otherwise free from objection, which carries with it no monopolistic menace, is not to be condemned as an undue restraint merely because it may effect a change in market conditions where the change would be in mitigation of recognized evils and would not impair, but rather foster, fair competitive opportunities. Appalachian Coals v. United States, 288 U.S. 344, 373, 374. Further, the dissemination of information is normally an aid to commerce. As free competition means a free and open market among both buyers and sellers, competition does not become less free merely because of the distribution of knowledge of the essential factors entering into commercial transactions. The natural effect of the acquisition of the wider and more scientific knowledge of business conditions on the minds of those engaged in commerce, and the consequent stabilizing of production and price, cannot be said to be an unreasonable restraint or in any respect unlawful. Maple Flooring Assn. v. United States, 268 U.S. 563, 582, 583. In that case, we decided that trade associations which openly and fairly gather and disseminate information as to the cost of their product, the volume of production, the actual price which the product has brought in past transactions, stocks of merchandise on hand, approximate costs of transportation, without reaching or attempting to reach an agreement or concerted action with respect to prices or production or restraining competition, do not fall under the interdiction of the Act. Id., p. 586. See, also, Cement Manufacturers Assn. v. United States, 268 U.S. 588, 604, 606.

The freedom of concerted action to improve conditions has an obvious limitation. The end does not justify illegal means. The endeavor to put a stop to illicit practices must not itself become illicit. As the statute draws the line at unreasonable restraints, a cooperative endeavor which transgresses that line cannot justify itself by pointing to evils afflicting the industry or to a laudable purpose to remove them. The decisions on which defendants rely emphasize this limitation. In Chicago Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, the Court found the assailed rule to be a reasonable regulation in a limited field. In the case of Appalachian Coals, supra, p. 375, the Court found that abundant competitive opportunities would exist in all markets where defendants' coal was sold, and that nothing had been shown to warrant the conclusion that defendants' plan would have an injurious effect upon competition in those markets. In Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 283 U.S. 163, relating to contracts concerning patents for cracking processes in producing gasoline, an examination of the transactions involved led to the conclusion "that no monopoly of any kind or restraint of interstate commerce" had been effected "either by means of the contracts or in some other way." Id., p. 179. And while the collection and dissemination of trade statistics are in themselves permissible and may be a useful adjunct of fair commerce, a combination to gather and supply information as a part of a plan to impose unwarrantable restrictions, as, for example, to curtail production and raise prices, has been condemned. American Column Co. v. United States, 257 U.S. 377, 411, 412; United States v. Linseed Oil Co., supra; Maple Flooring Assn. v. United States, supra, pp. 584, 585.

We have said that the Sherman Act, as a charter of freedom, has a generality and adaptability comparable to that found to be desirable in constitutional provisions. It does not go into detailed definitions. Thus in applying its broad prohibitions, each case demands a close scrutiny of its own facts. Questions of reasonableness are necessarily questions of relation and degree. In the instant case, a fact of outstanding importance is the relative position of defendants in the sugar industry. We have noted that the fifteen refiners, represented in the Institute, refine practically all the imported raw sugar processed in this country. They supply from 70 to 80 per cent. of the sugar consumed. Their refineries are in the East, South, and West, and their agreements and concerted action have a direct effect upon the entire sugar trade. While their product competes with beet sugar and "offshore" sugar, the maintenance of fair competition between the defendants themselves in the sale of domestic refined sugar is manifestly of serious public concern. Another outstanding fact is that defendants' product is a thoroughly standardized commodity. In their competition, price, rather than brand, is generally the vital consideration. The question of unreasonable restraint of competition thus relates in the main to competition in prices, terms and conditions of sales. The fact that, because sugar is a standardized commodity, there is a strong tendency to uniformity of price, makes it the more important that such opportunities as may exist for fair competition should not be impaired.

Defendants point to the abuses which existed before they formed the Institute, and to their remedial efforts. But the controversy that emerges is not as to the abuses which admittedly existed, but whether defendants' agreement and requirements went too far and imposed unreasonable restraints. After a hearing of extraordinary length, in which no pertinent fact was permitted to escape consideration, the trial court subjected the evidence to a thorough and acute analysis which has left but slight room for debate over matters of fact. Our examination of the record discloses no reason for overruling the court's findings in any matter essential to our decision.

In determining the relief to be afforded, appropriate regard should be had to the special and historic practice of the sugar industry. The restraints, found to be unreasonable, were the offspring of the basic agreement. The vice in that agreement was not in the mere open announcement of prices and terms in accordance with the custom of the trade. That practice which had grown out of the special character of the industry did not restrain competition. The trial court did not hold that practice to be illegal and we see no reason for condemning it. The unreasonable restraints which defendants imposed lay not in advance announcements, but in the steps taken to secure adherence, without deviation, to prices and terms thus announced. It was that concerted undertaking which cut off opportunities for variation in the course of competition however fair and appropriate they might be. But, in ending that restraint, the beneficial and curative agency of publicity should not be unnecessarily hampered. The trial court left defendants free to provide for immediate publicity as to prices and terms in all closed transactions. We think that a limitation to that sort of publicity fails to take proper account of the practice of the trade in selling on "moves," as already described, a practice in accordance with which the court found that "the great bulk of sugar always was and is purchased." That custom involves advance announcements, and it does not appear that arrangements merely to circulate or relay such announcements threaten competitive opportunities. On the other hand, such provision for publicity may be helpful in promoting fair competition. If the requirement that there must be adherence to prices and terms openly announced in advance is abrogated and the restraints which followed that requirement are removed, the just interests of competition will be safeguarded and the trade will still be left with whatever advantage may be incidental to its established practice.

The decree. — The court below did not dissolve the Institute. The practices which had been found to constitute unreasonable restraints were comprehensively enjoined. The injunction restrains defendants "individually and collectively, in connection with the sale, marketing, shipment, transportation, storage, distribution or delivery of refined sugar," from engaging with one another or with any competitor through any "program" in any of the activities separately described. The decree defines "program" as "any agreement, understanding or concerted action, including, but without limiting the generality of the foregoing, any rule, policy or code provision or interpretation, concertedly adopted or maintained."

Then follow forty-five specifications of prohibited action. As to seventeen of these paragraphs, defendants have withdrawn their assignments of error.

Paragraphs one and two of the specifications enjoin the carrying out of the open price plan so far as it seeks to compel uniform terms, regardless of circumstances, and an adherence to prices, terms, etc. announced in advance. These paragraphs cover any agreement or concerted action in

"1. Effectuating any general plan to give the same terms, conditions, or freight applications to customers, regardless of the varying circumstances of particular transactions or classes of transactions or regardless of the varying situation of particular refiners, distributors or customers or classes thereof;

"2. Selling only upon or adhering to prices, terms, conditions or freight applications announced, reported or relayed in advance of sale or refraining from deviating therefrom."

In view of those provisions, and of the other forty specified restrictions, we think that paragraphs three, four and five with respect to the reporting or relaying of information as to current or future prices should be eliminated. These paragraphs are as follows:

"3. Effectuating any system for or systematically reporting to or among one another or competitors or to a common agency, information as to current or future prices, terms, conditions, or freight applications, or lists or schedules of the same;

"4. Relaying by or through The Sugar Institute, Inc., or any other common agency, information as to current or future prices, terms, conditions, or freight applications or any list or schedule of the same;

"5. Giving any prior notice of any change or contemplated change in prices, terms, conditions, or freight applications, or relaying, reporting or announcing any such change in advance thereof."

Such reporting or relaying, as we have said, permits voluntary price announcements by individual refiners, in accordance with trade usage, to be circulated, and subject to the restrictions imposed by the decree does not appear to involve any unreasonable restraint of competition.

Paragraph seven relates to the collection and dissemination of statistical information, as follows:

"7. Effectuating any system of gathering and/or disseminating statistical information regarding melt, sales, deliveries, stocks on hand, stocks on consignment, stocks in transit, volume of sugar moved by differential or other particular routes or types of routes, new business or any other statistical information of a similar character, wherever and to the extent that said information is not made, or is not readily, fully and fairly available to the purchasing and distributing trade."

This provision was based upon the finding that "Perfect competition and defendants' professed policy of fostering such competition require that the purchasing trade as well as the sellers have the full, detailed information which defendants withheld." That ruling has appropriate reference to the statistical data which are specified in paragraph seven and to the withholding of which we have referred. In those data the purchasing and distributing trade have a legitimate interest. But it does not follow that the purchasing and distributing trade have such an interest in every detail of information which may be received by the Institute. Information may be received in relation to the affairs of refiners which may rightly be treated as having a confidential character and in which distributors and purchasers have no proper interest. To require, under the penalties of disobedience of the injunction, the dissemination of everything that the Institute may learn might well prejudice rather than serve the interests of fair competition and obstruct the useful and entirely lawful activities of the refiners.

In this view we think that the clause in paragraph seven "or any other statistical information of a similar character" should be eliminated. The preceding specifications as to melt, sales, deliveries, stocks on hand, on consignment, or in transit, and as to transportation and new business, appear to be adequate. The words "of a similar character" have no clearly defined meaning and would place the defendants under an equivocal restriction which may do more harm than good. With the removal of that clause and the placing of the word "and" before the words "new business," paragraph seven is approved.

Following the provisions for injunction, the decree properly provides that jurisdiction is retained for the purpose of "enforcing, enlarging or modifying" its terms. It is further provided that the injunction is without prejudice to application by any party for modification in order to permit the adoption of any "program" that may be permissible under "the National Industrial Recovery Act" of June 16, 1933, or the "Emergency Farm Relief Act" of May 12, 1933, or "any other present or future statutes of the United States." This subdivision of the decree should be modified so as to refer simply to "any applicable Act of Congress."

The decree is modified in the particulars above stated and, as thus modified, is affirmed.

Modified and affirmed.

MR. JUSTICE SUTHERLAND and MR. JUSTICE STONE took no part in the consideration and decision of this cause.


Summaries of

Sugar Institute v. United States

U.S.
Mar 30, 1936
297 U.S. 553 (1936)

affirming district court's remedial decree requiring public dissemination of the information gathered

Summary of this case from Todd v. Exxon Corp.

explaining that "steps ... to secure adherence, without deviation, to prices and terms ... announced" are illegal

Summary of this case from Conn. Fine Wine & Spirits, LLC v. Seagull

noting that steps taken to secure "adherence, without deviation, to the prices and terms . . . announced" violate § 1 of the Sherman Act

Summary of this case from TFWS, Inc. v. Franchot

noting that "steps taken to secure adherence, without deviation, to prices and terms . . . announced" violate § 1

Summary of this case from TFWS, Inc. v. Schaefer

In Sugar Institute v. United States, 297 U.S. 553, at page 600, 56 S.Ct. 629, at page 643, 80 L.Ed. 859, the Court said of the Sherman Act: "Thus in applying its broad prohibitions, each case demands a close scrutiny of its own facts.

Summary of this case from Bale v. Glasgow Tobacco Board of Trade, Inc.

In Sugar Institute, Inc., v. United States, 1936, 297 U.S. 553, 599-600, 56 S.Ct. 629, 642, 80 L.Ed. 859, the court said, "And, while the collection and dissemination of trade statistics are in themselves permissible and may be a useful adjunct of fair commerce, a combination to gather and supply information as a part of a plan to impose unwarrantable restrictions, as, for example, to curtail production and raise prices, has been condemned * * * each case demands a close scrutiny of its own facts."

Summary of this case from Morton Salt Company v. United States

In Sugar Institute, Inc., v. United States, 1936, 297 U.S. 553, 582, 56 S.Ct. 629, 80 L.Ed. 859, the Court struck down an agreement which included a reporting feature with "a requirement of adherence, without deviation, to the prices and terms publicly announced."

Summary of this case from Tag MFRS. Institute v. Federal Trade Commission

In Sugar Institute, the Court held that an agreement to adhere to previously announced prices and terms of sale is unlawful per se under the Sherman Act, even though the particular prices and terms were not themselves fixed by private agreement.

Summary of this case from 83 Op. Att'y Gen. 3
Case details for

Sugar Institute v. United States

Case Details

Full title:SUGAR INSTITUTE, INC. ET AL. v . UNITED STATES

Court:U.S.

Date published: Mar 30, 1936

Citations

297 U.S. 553 (1936)
56 S. Ct. 629

Citing Cases

Tag MFRS. Institute v. Federal Trade Commission

Presumably this is because such secrecy more readily suggests the inference that the agreement is inspired by…

Trade Comm'n v. Cement Institute

Disposition of this question brings us to the related contention that there was no substantial evidence to…