From Casetext: Smarter Legal Research

Biddle v. The Walt Disney Co.

United States District Court, Northern District of California
Sep 29, 2023
696 F. Supp. 3d 865 (N.D. Cal. 2023)

Opinion

Case No. 5:22-cv-07317-EJD

2023-09-29

Heather BIDDLE, et al., Plaintiffs, v. The WALT DISNEY COMPANY, Defendant.

Brian James Dunne, Edward Maxwell Grauman, Pro Hac Vice, Bathaee Dunne LLP, Austin, TX, Yavar Bathaee, Andrew C. Wolinsky, Bathaee Dunne LLP, New York, NY, Allison Watson Cross, Bathaee Dunne LLP, Costa Mesa, CA, Chad Emerson Bell, Pro Hac Vice, Korein Tillery LLC, Chicago, IL, Christopher M. Burke, Walter W. Noss, Yifan Kate Lv, Korein Tillery, PC, San Diego, CA, for Plaintiffs Heather Biddle, Jeffrey Kaplan, Zachary Roberts, Joel Wilson. Chad Emerson Bell, Pro Hac Vice, Korein Tillery LLC, Chicago, IL, Christopher M. Burke, Walter W. Noss, Yifan Kate Lv, Korein Tillery, PC, San Diego, CA, Brian James Dunne, Bathaee Dunne LLP, Austin, TX, for Plaintiffs Scott Thompson, Angel Hernandez, Douglas Yarema, Tamika Anderson, David Kenward, Angela Heard, Utica Cason, Nicholas Dowd, Don Knoch, Connie Harrison, Laura Molina, Steven Tucker, Dustin Shapiro, Dev Singh, David Show, William Gaskins. Antony L. Ryan, Pro Hac Vice, David Korn, Pro Hac Vice, Joe Wesley Earnhardt, Pro Hac Vice, Cravath, Swaine Moore LLP, New York, NY, Christopher C. Wheeler, Esq., Daniel Antonio Contreras, Douglas Rea Young, Farella Braun & Martel LLP, San Francisco, CA, for Defendant.


Brian James Dunne, Edward Maxwell Grauman, Pro Hac Vice, Bathaee Dunne LLP, Austin, TX, Yavar Bathaee, Andrew C. Wolinsky, Bathaee Dunne LLP, New York, NY, Allison Watson Cross, Bathaee Dunne LLP, Costa Mesa, CA, Chad Emerson Bell, Pro Hac Vice, Korein Tillery LLC, Chicago, IL, Christopher M. Burke, Walter W. Noss, Yifan Kate Lv, Korein Tillery, PC, San Diego, CA, for Plaintiffs Heather Biddle, Jeffrey Kaplan, Zachary Roberts, Joel Wilson. Chad Emerson Bell, Pro Hac Vice, Korein Tillery LLC, Chicago, IL, Christopher M. Burke, Walter W. Noss, Yifan Kate Lv, Korein Tillery, PC, San Diego, CA, Brian James Dunne, Bathaee Dunne LLP, Austin, TX, for Plaintiffs Scott Thompson, Angel Hernandez, Douglas Yarema, Tamika Anderson, David Kenward, Angela Heard, Utica Cason, Nicholas Dowd, Don Knoch, Connie Harrison, Laura Molina, Steven Tucker, Dustin Shapiro, Dev Singh, David Show, William Gaskins. Antony L. Ryan, Pro Hac Vice, David Korn, Pro Hac Vice, Joe Wesley Earnhardt, Pro Hac Vice, Cravath, Swaine Moore LLP, New York, NY, Christopher C. Wheeler, Esq., Daniel Antonio Contreras, Douglas Rea Young, Farella Braun & Martel LLP, San Francisco, CA, for Defendant.

ORDER GRANTING IN PART AND DENYING IN PART MOTION TO DISMISS; TERMINATING AS MOOT MOTION TO STAY DISCOVERY

Re: ECF No. 19, 43 EDWARD J. DAVILA, United States District Judge

Plaintiffs Heather Biddle, Jeffrey Kaplan, Zachary Robertys, and Joel Wilson bring this antitrust putative class action lawsuit against Defendant The Walt Disney Company ("Disney") on behalf of all monthly subscribers of YouTube TV, from the period beginning April 1, 2019, through the present (hereinafter "Plaintiffs"). Class Action Compl. ("CAC"), ECF No. 1 ¶¶ 1, 345.

Pending before the Court are Defendant's motions to dismiss at ECF No. 19 and stay discovery at ECF No. 43. The Court heard oral argument on Defendant's motion to dismiss on July 13, 2023. The Court took Defendant's motion to stay under submission without oral argument pursuant to Civil Local Rule 7-1(b). For the reasons discussed herein, Defendant's motion to dismiss is GRANTED IN PART and DENIED IN PART and Defendant's motion to stay is TERMINATED AS MOOT.

I. BACKGROUND

Plaintiffs are four individuals who reside in California, Arizona, Indiana, and Kentucky, and are current subscribers of YouTube TV. CAC ¶¶ 9-13. Plaintiffs allege that Disney, through its subsidiaries ESPN and Hulu (collectively, the "Disney Entities"), entered into anticompetitive carriage agreements. Id. ¶ 3. The Disney Entities allegedly conspired with YouTube TV to inflate prices of monthly subscriptions of the Streaming Live Pay TV market ("SLPTV"), set a price floor for the SLPTV market in violation of the Sherman Act § 1, and reduce consumer choice. Id. ¶¶ 8, 342, 356. Plaintiffs seek injunctive relief, treble damages, attorneys' fees and costs, and compensation for overpayment for SLPTV services. Id. ¶¶ 373-75.

A. ESPN Affiliate Fees and Carriage Agreements

Disney controls certain network channels such as ABC Television Network, the Disney Channel, ESPN, and FX. Id. ¶¶ 16, 308. Disney owns an 80% interest share of ESPN with the remaining 20% owned by the Hearst Corporation. Id. ¶ 16. ESPN provides sports coverage as a part of cable packages. Id. ¶ 27. Since its inception in 1978, ESPN has gained significant popularity. Id. ¶¶ 27, 33-34. In 2012, ESPN expanded into several sister channels, including ESPN2, ESPNews, ESPN Classic, and ESPNU. Id. ¶ 33. Over the years, ESPN has brought in billions of dollars per year in fees to Disney from cable television networks in the United States. Id. ¶¶ 42-43.

ESPN generates "affiliate fees," or fees charged to cable companies to broadcast a cable TV channel as part of a cable package or bundle. Id. ¶ 45. ESPN's affiliate fees are the most expensive affiliate fees charged to cable providers in the country. Id. ¶¶ 48, 323. For example, in 2012, ESPN fees were $5.13 per subscriber per month and, by 2016, the price climbed to $6.55, and over $9 per month in 2017. Id. ¶¶ 45, 47, 51. Comparatively, most channels in 2017 charged $1 per month in affiliate fees. Id. ¶¶ 48, 51. These costs are passed onto consumers via the cost of the bundle. Id. ¶ 323. Plaintiffs allege that through inflated affiliate fees for ESPN and its sister networks—which have steadily ballooned in price each year—Disney has direct input into TV bundle prices offered by its direct competitors. Id. ¶¶ 46, 51.

Central to the CAC are the "web of carriage agreements" the Disney Entities maintain with all SLPTV market participants, including its leading competitors DirecTV Stream and YouTube TV. Id. ¶¶ 5, 303. The carriage agreements each contain an ESPN base term requirement and a most favored nation ("MFN") clause. Id. ¶ 306.

ESPN Base Term Requirement: Disney's agreements require cable providers to include ESPN in the "basic" or cheapest cable or satellite packages. Id. ¶¶ 54, 57. A competitor that wishes to carry ESPN must agree to the base term requirement, meaning that if any SLPTV service carries ESPN as a part of any of its bundles, it must also carry ESPN in its base or cheapest bundle. Id. ¶¶ 307, 335. Put another way, to avoid including ESPN in the cheapest bundle, a provider cannot carry ESPN in any of its bundles. The term restricts the ability of Disney's competitors carrying ESPN to provide an option to its SLPTV-customers that excludes ESPN. Id. ¶ 306. Absent this requirement, a competitor in the SLPTV market carrying ESPN could provide a "skinny" bundle to consumers that excludes ESPN. Id. ¶ 309. All three of the market-leading SLPTV services—YouTube TV, Hulu + Live TV, and DirecTV Stream—offer live television options with ESPN as part of the base bundle. Id. ¶¶ 310, 335. This means that substantially all consumers in the market must pay for ESPN. Id. ¶ 336.

MFN Price Term: Disney also imposes MFN clauses in the carriage agreements with cable providers. Id. ¶ 55. Plaintiffs allege the MFN price term "requires Disney to provide the counterparty with the lowest price for ESPN and other channels offered to any other market participant." Id. ¶ 312. In other words, if Disney provides another service a lower price, then that price becomes the applicable price for its counterparty. Id. ¶ 313.

B. Disney's Entry into the SLPTV Market

Around 2013, internet streaming platforms like HBO, Amazon Prime, and Netflix were popular platforms for watching premium video content. Id. 72. However, consumers still needed a cable or satellite TV subscription to stream live television. Id. Some consumers opted not to purchase a cable or satellite package, instead purchasing internet-streaming platform subscriptions—a process referred to as "cord cutting." Id. ¶ 73. Despite this trend, the majority of households (approximately 90%) maintained cable or satellite subscriptions. Id. ¶ 75.

In 2015, cable-only subscription services began to offer subscriptions to their content entirely over the internet decoupled from cable or satellite TV packages—a process referred to as "de-bundling." Id. ¶ 81. For example, in 2014 HBO announced that it planned to de-bundle its content from traditional cable and satellite TV plans upon the release of its HBO GO streaming service, which would be available to people without a pay-TV subscription. Id. ¶¶ 82-83. Studies at the time suggest that cord cutting increased in the mid-2010s, meaning fewer consumers purchased cable and satellite TV packages. Id. ¶ 83. However, approximately 76% of Americans still subscribed to cable or satellite TV. Id.

The rise of Virtual Multichannel Video Programming Distributors ("vMVPD") that streamed live TV channels over the internet began around this time. Id. ¶¶ 81, 132. Companies like YouTube, Hulu, and Sling began offering live pay television that rivaled cable and satellite TV offerings. Id. ¶ 131. Live streaming TV provided an alternative to cable at a much lower cost. Id. ¶ 137. With live internet-streaming platforms, consumers no longer needed to purchase satellite or cable to view live channels. Id. ¶ 72. Unlike traditional MVPDs, i.e., cable and satellite TV services, vMVPDs did not use proprietary cable or dish transmission media, instead relying on existing Internet infrastructure to transmit live pay TV channels over the internet. Id. ¶ 132.

From 2012 to 2017, Disney lost millions of customer-subscribers, from 100M down to 88M, due to cord cutting. Id. ¶¶ 96-97. Cord cutting or de-bundling enabled consumers to opt-out of paying ESPN affiliate fees because subscribers could choose which channels would be included in the bundle, meaning they could choose to exclude ESPN from their bundle. Id. ¶¶ 93-94. For example, in 2017, new companies, like Verizon, began providing live TV cable packages over the Internet. Id. ¶ 100. They provided "skinny" or basic bundles that were less bloated (i.e., less expansive) than cable packages and allowed subscribers to choose channels. Id. ¶¶ 105, 112-13.

In 2017, Disney announced that it would acquire 21st Century Fox. Id. ¶ 145. At the time of acquisition, Fox had a one third interest in the live-streaming internet service, Hulu. Id. ¶ 153. By 2019, Disney obtained 67% interest in Hulu, or full "operational" control. Id. ¶ 150. Hulu is a subscription-based video streaming service that offers video on demand services and live streaming television services. Id. ¶ 17. Hulu's live streaming television service (or vMVPD) is called Hulu + live TV. Id.

Plaintiffs allege that Disney has agreed to purchase the remaining 33% ownership interest from NBC Universal in January 2024. Id.

Since the acquisition Disney has substantially raised Hulu's subscription prices as well as the ESPN affiliate fees. Id. ¶¶ 163-64. In November 2019, Disney raised the price of Hulu's + Live TV offering by $10, bringing the cost of the base package to $54.99 per month. Id. ¶ 154. At the time, Hulu + Live TV had 2.7 million subscribers—approximately half of all subscribers to streaming live TV platforms. Id. Plaintiffs allege that competing platforms followed Hulu and increased the cost of their packages. Id. ¶ 155. In the following years, AT&T DirecTV's streaming live TV offering raised its base package by $15, and one year later, YouTube TV raised prices by $15 per month—both rising to $65 per month. Id. ¶¶ 156, 159.

As the expiration of the carriage agreements neared, the Disney Entities needed to negotiate new agreements with SLPTV providers. Id. ¶¶ 164-65. The first carriage agreement with AT&T DirecTV expired in the Fall of 2019. Id. ¶ 168. AT&T was not initially willing to give into the Disney Entities' carriage agreement demands. Id. ¶ 171. The Disney Entities began a public campaign warning subscribers of the impending loss of access to ESPN due to the companies' carriage dispute. Id. ¶¶ 168-70. The parties reached a deal five days later. Id. ¶ 171. In the weeks following the deal, AT&T DirecTV raised the price of its live TV streaming service base package by $15, to $65 per month. Id. ¶ 172. AT&T released a statement attributing the price hike to the increased cost to deliver content to customers. Id.

From 2019 to 2022, the Disney Entities entered into a series of carriage agreements with SLPTV providers that contained the ESPN "base package" requirement and MFN clauses—resulting in price increases to these streaming platform's subscription plans. Id. ¶ 174.

AT&T's DirecTV: Disney entered into a new carriage agreement with AT&T's DirecTV. Id. ¶ 171. This agreement contained a base term that forced DirecTV to include ESPN in its most basic package, as well as an MFN clause. Id. ¶ 174. In the following weeks, AT&T raised the price of its live TV streaming service base package by $15, totaling $65 per month. Id. ¶ 172. AT&T released a statement that their adjusted pricing "reflect[s] the cost to deliver content to our customers." Id. ¶ 172. At the time, Disney Hulu + Live TV was priced at only $55 per month—$10 less expensive than AT&T's DirecTV. Id. ¶ 174.

Google's YouTube TV: YouTube TV is the largest SLPTV provider in the U.S. Id. ¶ 274. Disney had a legacy carriage agreement with Google's YouTube TV that required Google to carry ESPN as a part of its basic streaming live TV package. Id. ¶ 180. Google's prices mirrored Disney's price increases until 2021, when the agreement was set to expire. Id. ¶¶ 103, 184. The parties began to negotiate a new carriage agreement. Id. ¶ 184. Google threatened to offer a base package without ESPN and publicly stated that having ESPN in its basic package increased the package cost by $15 per month (an increase from $50 to $65 per month). Id. ¶ 185. Without ESPN channels, YouTube TV said it would drop its monthly subscription price from $64.99 to $49.99. Id. ¶ 192. Nevertheless, the parties entered a new carriage agreement in 2021. Id. ¶ 194. Google's YouTube TV kept ESPN in its base package and increased its subscription cost to $65 per month. Id. ¶¶ 194, 196.

Dish's Sling TV: Disney also had a legacy carriage agreement with Dish's Sling TV that required Sling TV to include ESPN in its basic bundle. Id. ¶ 201. The legacy agreement expired in 2022. Id. ¶ 204. Negotiations faltered over the MFN clause, and Disney cut Sling TV's access to its channels. Id. ¶¶ 205, 208. After negotiations failed, Dish released a statement that Disney was trying to hike up its affiliate fees by "exploit[ing] its market position." Id. ¶ 206. Disney and Sling TV reached a new carriage agreement in 2022. Id. ¶ 210. Dish TV increased the price of its base package by $5 per month, totaling $40 per month, because of the increased cost of "programming." Id. ¶¶ 211, 214.
While these negotiations were going on, in 2020, Disney again raised Hulu Live + TV's price by $10, bringing its base plan to $64.99 per month. Id. ¶ 160.

At the time Dish Sling TV negotiated renewal of the carriage agreements, Disney had already entered into carriage agreements with Google's YouTube TV and AT&T's DirecTV Stream. Id. ¶ 209. These agreements increased the ESPN fees and contained MFN clauses. Id. Due to the MFN clauses, Disney would either need to lower fees for both Google YouTube TV and AT&T DirecTV, or raise ESPN fees for Dish Sling TV. Id.

Plaintiffs specifically allege that, since Disney took over Hulu, the price delta between the cost of cable TV packages and live-streaming packages narrowed from $15 to $35 per month to nearly identical monthly prices to cable packages. Id. ¶ 217. Hulu and YouTube TV are the two top streaming TV providers, capturing 70% of all streaming love TV subscribers. Id. ¶ 219. Both providers charge approximately the same subscription price. Id. ¶ 220. YouTube TV's base package costs $64.99 per month, and Hulu + Live TV costs $69.99 per month, with both services reaching prices well above $70 per month when additional options are added. Id.

C. Relevant Market

The CAC defines the relevant market as the SLPTV Market. Id. ¶ 223. SLPTV is a distinct sub-market of the "Live Pay TV Market" ("the "LPTV Market"), or providers of live television including cable or satellite television providers. Id. ¶ 223. The SLPTV Market includes subscription-based services that provide access to live television channels over a broadband internet connection, provided as bundles of channels. Id. ¶ 224. SLPTV providers create "basic packages" which include the minimum number of channels a subscriber must purchase access to as part of a subscription. Id. ¶ 225. Subscribers cannot choose individual channels to include in SLPTV subscriptions. Id. SLPTV products are generally available on multiple devices, including tablets, smart phones, PCs, laptops, televisions, and game consoles. Id. ¶ 227.

Plaintiffs allege the following SLPTV market participants: Google's YouTube TV, Disney's Hulu + Live TV, AT&T's DirecTV Stream (previously branded DirecTV Now and AT&T Now), Dish's Sling TV, and Fubo TV. Id. ¶ 273. At the time of filing the CAC, YouTube TV has the largest market concentration with over 5,000,000 subscribers, followed by Hulu + Live TV with approximately 4,100,000 subscribers. Id. ¶ 274. Participants' revenue shares are proportionally distributed with market share. Id. ¶ 275. Plaintiffs allege the SLPTV market is highly concentrated. Id. ¶ 276. The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) of the market shares is 2794, which exceeds the HHIs the DOJ considered to be "moderately concentrated" or 1,500 and 2,500 HHIs. Id. ¶¶ 276-77.

D. Procedural History

On November 18, 2022, Plaintiffs filed the instant action. On January 31, 2023, Disney moved to dismiss the action in its entirety. Mot. to Dismiss the Pls.' Compl. ("MTD"), ECF No. 19. Plaintiffs oppose the motion. Pls.' Opp'n to Def. The Walt Disney Co.'s Mot. to Dismiss the CAC ("Opp'n to MTD"), ECF No. 36. While the motion to dismiss was pending, Disney moved to stay discovery pending resolution of the motion to dismiss. Mot. to Stay ("MTS"), ECF No. 43. Plaintiffs oppose staying discovery. Pls.' Opp'n to Def. The Walt Disney Co.'s Mot. to Stay ("Opp'n to MTS"), ECF No. 47.

II. LEGAL STANDARD

Rule 8(a)(2) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure requires a complaint to include "a short and plain statement of the claim showing that the pleader is entitled to relief." A complaint that fails to meet this standard may be dismissed pursuant to Rule 12(b)(6). Rule 8(a) requires a plaintiff to plead "enough facts to state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face." Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 570, 127 S.Ct. 1955, 167 L.Ed.2d 929 (2007). "A claim has facial plausibility when the plaintiff pleads factual content that allows the court to draw the reasonable inference that the defendant is liable for the misconduct alleged." Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 678, 129 S.Ct. 1937, 173 L.Ed.2d 868 (2009). While a plaintiff must allege "more than a sheer possibility that a defendant has acted unlawfully," the plausibility standard "is not akin to a probability requirement." Id.

For purposes of ruling on a Rule 12(b)(6) motion, the Court generally "accept[s] factual allegations in the complaint as true and construe[s] the pleadings in the light most favorable to the nonmoving party." Manzarek v. St. Paul Fire & Marine Ins. Co., 519 F.3d 1025, 1031 (9th Cir. 2008). The Court need not, however, "assume the truth of legal conclusions merely because they are cast in the form of factual allegations." Fayer v. Vaughn, 649 F.3d 1061, 1064 (9th Cir. 2011) (per curiam). Mere "conclusory allegations of law and unwarranted inferences are insufficient to defeat a motion to dismiss." Adams v. Johnson, 355 F.3d 1179, 1183 (9th Cir. 2004). The Court may also "look beyond the plaintiff's complaint to matters of public record" without converting the Rule 12(b)(6) motion into a motion for summary judgment. Shaw v. Hahn, 56 F.3d 1128, 1129 (9th Cir. 1995).

III. DISCUSSION

A. Sherman Act § 1

Plaintiffs allege a singular cause of action for restraint of trade under Sherman Act § 1. Section 1 provides that "[e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal." 15 U.S.C. § 1. A plaintiff asserting a claim under § 1 must plead: "(1) a contract, combination or conspiracy among two or more persons or distinct business entities; (2) which is intended to restrain or harm trade; (3) which actually injures competition; and (4) harm to the plaintiffs from the anticompetitive conduct." Name.Space, Inc. v. Internet Corp. for Assigned Names & Numbers, 795 F.3d 1124, 1129 (9th Cir. 2015) (quotations omitted). Because § 1 does not forbid all unreasonable restraints of trade, "the crucial question is whether the challenged anticompetitive conduct stems from independent decision or from an agreement, tacit or express." Twombly, 550 U.S. at 553, 127 S.Ct. 1955. Generally, "the accepted standard for testing whether a practice restrains trade in violation of § 1" is the "rule of reason" standard. Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 885, 127 S.Ct. 2705, 168 L.Ed.2d 623 (2007). A plaintiff may also allege that a restraint is one that has already been "deemed unlawful per se." State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 10, 118 S.Ct. 275, 139 L.Ed.2d 199 (1997). Plaintiffs allege both theories in the CAC.

Disney argues that (1) Plaintiffs per se claims should be dismissed because Plaintiffs allege a vertical restraint, and even if the alleged restraints were horizontal, Plaintiffs have not stated a per se violation; (2) Plaintiffs fail to state a claim under the rule of reason because Plaintiffs have failed to plead a relevant antitrust market in which Disney has power and fails to plead agreements that unreasonably restrain trade; and (3) Plaintiffs claims for damages are barred. The Court addresses each argument in turn.

1. Plaintiffs fail to allege a per se violation of § 1

Antitrust conspiracies are generally classified as either vertical restraints, such as an agreement made between a manufacturer and a retailer, or as horizontal restraints, meaning agreements among competitors. In re Musical Instruments & Equip. Antitrust Litig., 798 F.3d 1186, 1191 (9th Cir. 2015). Courts must "examin[e] the economic relationship between the parties" to determine whether it is categorized as horizontal or vertical. Dimidowich v. Bell & Howell, 803 F.2d 1473, 1480 (9th Cir. 1986); see also Bus. Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 485 U.S. 717, 730 n.4, 108 S.Ct. 1515, 99 L.Ed.2d 808 (1988) (characterization of the restraint does not depend on whether the anticompetitive effects are horizontal or vertical). Vertical restraints are presumptively examined under a rule of reason analysis. Texaco Inc. v. Dagher, 547 U.S. 1, 5, 126 S.Ct. 1276, 164 L.Ed.2d 1 (2006). This analysis accounts for the fact that a vertical restraint "may have procompetitive justifications that benefit consumers." In re Musical Instruments, 798 F.3d at 1192. Conversely, "per se liability is reserved for only those agreements that are 'so plainly anticompetitive that no elaborate study of the industry is needed to establish their illegality.' " Texaco Inc. v. Dagher, 547 U.S. 1, 5, 126 S.Ct. 1276, 164 L.Ed.2d 1 (2006) (quoting Nat'l Soc. of Pro. Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 692, 98 S.Ct. 1355, 55 L.Ed.2d 637 (1978)). This is because conduct deemed per se unlawful "always or almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease output." Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 19-20 (1979). To justify a per se prohibition, a restraint must have "manifestly anticompetitive" effects. Cont'l T. V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 50, 97 S.Ct. 2549, 53 L.Ed.2d 568 (1977). In general, only agreements between competitors to restrain trade, i.e., horizontal agreements, qualify as unreasonable per se. Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 585 U.S. 529, 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2283-84, 201 L.Ed.2d 678 (2018). Once a plaintiff has established the existence of a horizontal agreement, "no further inquiry into the practice's actual effect on the market or the parties' intentions is necessary to establish a § 1 violation." In re Musical Instruments, 798 F.3d at 1191.

The Court notes that "not all horizontal agreements between competitors are per se invalid." Paladin Assocs., Inc. v. Montana Power Co., 328 F.3d 1145, 1155 (9th Cir. 2003).

It is undisputed that ESPN executes carriage agreements with SLPTV providers in which ESPN provides network channels to subscription-based streaming service platforms such as AT&T's DirecTV and Google's YouTube TV. It is also undisputed that Disney owns an 80% interest share of ESPN and a 66% controlling interest in a subscription-based streaming service platform, Hulu, which provides a live streaming service called Hulu + Live TV that competes in the SLPTV market. Plaintiffs allege that the Disney Entities and SLPTV providers entered into carriage agreements containing the ESPN base term and MFN clause, which purportedly restrains competition. CAC ¶¶ 311-12. Plaintiffs characterize these carriage agreements as horizontal agreements between direct competitors because Disney and its subsidiaries purportedly function as one entity or enterprise. See Copperweld Corp. v. Indep. Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 771, 104 S.Ct. 2731, 81 L.Ed.2d 628 (1984).

Disney argues, however, that the carriage agreements are vertical restraints because they are agreements between competitors at the same level of the distribution chain. MTD at 8-9. According to Disney, the carriage agreement is a classic supplier-distributor relationship: a television network programmer, such as ESPN, agrees to sell distribution rights to its ESPN network and, in exchange, the SLPTV provider pays a fee to carry the channel. Mot. at 2; see Bus. Elecs. Corp., 485 U.S. at 730, 108 S.Ct. 1515 (defining "agreement[s] between firms at different levels of distribution," such as between a supplier and distributor, as "vertical restraints"). The determinative consideration, according to Disney, is the parties' relationship with respect to the agreement at issue. Using this framework, Disney asserts it is akin to a dual distributorship "in which a manufacturer operates at two distinct levels of the distribution chain in the same market by acting as both a supplier and a distributor of its own products." Dimidowich v. Bell & Howell, 803 F.2d 1473, 1480 (9th Cir. 1986) (explaining that dual distributorships are vertical and analyzed under the rule of reason).

Whether a restraint is characterized as horizontal or vertical depends on the relationship between the parties. See Bus. Elecs. Corp., 485 U.S. at 730, 108 S.Ct. 1515 (holding that "[r]estraints imposed by agreement between competitors have traditionally been denominated as horizontal restraints, and those imposed by agreement between firms at different levels of distribution as vertical restraints."). " 'An arrangement is said to be 'horizontal' when its participants are (1) either actual or potential rivals at the time the agreement is made; and (2) the agreement eliminates some avenue of rivalry among them.' " In re Sulfuric Acid Antitrust Litig., 743 F.Supp.2d 827, 867 (N.D. Ill. 2010) (quoting 11 H. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 1901b, p. 203 (2d ed. 2005)). Here, the only agreements at issue are carriage agreements between ESPN and SLPTV providers in which ESPN provides the ESPN network to SLPTV streaming platforms within the same distribution chain—a relationship that is categorically vertical. United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 608, 92 S.Ct. 1126, 31 L.Ed.2d 515 (1972) (defining vertical restraint as a "combination[ ] of persons at different levels of the market structure, e.g., manufacturers and distributors"). Plaintiffs do not allege that ESPN competes with the SLPTV providers, nor do Plaintiffs allege that Hulu—or even Disney through Hulu—entered into a horizontal agreement with a competitor.

Relying on Copperweld, Plaintiffs characterize the carriage agreements as horizontal restraints because the Disney Entities operate as a "single economic unit." Opp'n at 7. Plaintiffs specifically allege that Disney operates both Hulu and ESPN with "unfettered control and a unity of interest and purpose" such that ESPN, Hulu, and Disney all function as a "single economic unit" under Disney's operational control. CAC ¶¶ 17-19. In Copperweld, the Supreme Court considered antitrust liability of parents and subsidiaries, holding that a parent and its wholly owned subsidiary cannot conspire with each other for purposes of Section 1. Copperweld Corp., 467 U.S. at 777, 104 S.Ct. 2731. In reaching this conclusion, the Court reasoned that "the coordinated activity of a parent and its wholly owned subsidiary must be viewed as that of a single enterprise for purposes of § 1 of the Sherman Act. A parent and its wholly owned subsidiary have a complete unity of interest." Id. at 771, 104 S.Ct. 2731 (emphasis added); see also id. at 772 n.18, 104 S.Ct. 2731 ("[T]he parent and the subsidiary must be viewed as a single economic unit.").

Later, in Arandell Corporation v. Centerpoint Energy Services, Inc., the Ninth Circuit interpreted Copperweld as follows:

If "a parent and a wholly owned subsidiary always have a 'unity of purpose' " and act as a "single enterprise" whenever they engage in "coordinated activity," then a subsidiary such as [defendant] as a matter of law cannot innocently advance an anticompetitive scheme . . . for a legitimate business purpose, while its parent and sister companies purposely advance the very same scheme . . . for an illegal, anticompetitive purpose.

. . .

In sum, Copperweld supports the following rule: A wholly owned subsidiary that engages in coordinated activity in furtherance
of the anticompetitive scheme of its parent and/or commonly owned affiliates is deemed to engage in such coordinated activity with the purposes of the single "economic unit" of which it is a part.
900 F.3d 623, 630-32 (9th Cir. 2018) (emphasis in original).

Divorced from its context, Plaintiff's interpret Copperweld and Arandell as suggesting that the carriage agreements between ESPN and SLPTV providers must be construed as agreements between the Disney Entities as a whole (i.e., ESPN, Disney, and Hulu) and the SLPTV providers, in effect dissolving the separate corporate personalities if the parent and subsidiary. Thus, because ESPN's parent company, Disney, also owns controlling interest in an SLPTV provider (Hulu) that competes in the same product market as the SLPTV providers contracting with ESPN (DirecTV Stream), the carriage agreements are horizontal restraints for § 1 purposes. However, Plaintiffs fail to cite a single case in this district that permits such an expansive reading of Copperweld.

Many courts in this district—including this Court—have applied Copperweld's "single enterprise" language to establish a subsidiaries' and/or an affiliates' individual participation in an anticompetitive conspiracy by alleging the entities are part of a "corporate family" that "operates as a single enterprise" for pleading purposes. See, e.g., Hightower v. Celestron Acquisition, LLC, No. 5:20-CV-03639-EJD, 2021 WL 2224148, at *10 (N.D. Cal. June 2, 2021); Jones v. Micron Tech. Inc., 400 F. Supp. 3d 897, 923 (N.D. Cal. 2019); In re Cathode Ray Tube (CRT) Antitrust Litig., 738 F. Supp. 2d 1011, 1019-22 (N.D. Cal. 2010); In re TFT-LCD, 599 F.Supp.2d 1179, 1184-85 (N.D. Cal. 2009). Plaintiffs cite the Undersigned's decision in Hightower in support of its application of Copperweld. However, this Court's application of Copperweld was confined to the narrow context of whether plaintiffs sufficiently alleged that each defendant participated in the alleged conspiracy by nature of belonging to a corporate family that operated as a single enterprise. The Court declines to expand Copperweld's scope beyond this context. See Mitchael v. Intracorp, Inc., 179 F.3d 847, 857 (10th Cir. 1999) (declining to hold that a subsidiary and its parent as "one entity for all § 1 purposes, and either one can be liable for conspiring to restrain trade").

Not all the cited cases refer to Copperweld or specifically reference a "single enterprise." See In re Cathode Ray Tube, 738 F. Supp. 2d 1011; Jones, 400 F. Supp. 3d 897; cf. Hightower, 2021 WL 2224148 (discussing Copperweld and whether defendant entities operate as a single enterprise). However, each case describes the elements necessary to allege that a corporate family functions as a single enterprise: "that individual corporate participants and their agents: (i) "did not always know the corporate affiliation of their counterparts;" (ii) acted on behalf of every company in their family; and (iii) entered into agreements on behalf of their respective corporate families." Jones, 400 F. Supp. 3d at 922.

Finally, while some vertical agreements may constitute a per se violation, Plaintiff has failed to allege a per se anticompetitive restraint. See Brantley v. NBC Universal, Inc., 675 F.3d 1192 (9th Cir. 2012). A restraint traditionally subject to per se treatment will only be found to be per se illegal if it "facially appears to be one that would almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease output," i.e., if it is a naked restraint on trade. Nat'l Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 100, 104 S.Ct. 2948, 82 L.Ed.2d 70 (1984) (citation omitted). Typical examples of per se restraints include agreements between competitors to fix prices, divide markets, and refuse to deal. In re Musical Instruments, 798 F.3d at 1191. Here, Plaintiffs allege that the combined effect of contractual restraints—the ESPN base term and the MFN clause—in Disney's carriage agreements allow Disney to set prices in the SLPTV market by forcing a minimum price on the SLPTV market. Id. ¶¶ 361-64. While MFN clauses can be used for anticompetitive ends, they are not per se unlawful. See, e.g., Blue Cross & Blue Shield United of Wisconsin v. Marshfield Clinic, 65 F.3d 1406, 1415 (7th Cir. 1995) (MFN clauses do not constitute price-fixing); In re Elec. Books Antitrust Litig., 859 F. Supp. 2d 671, 692 (S.D.N.Y. 2012) ("MFN clauses are customarily subject to the rule of reason."). With respect to the ESPN base term, Plaintiffs allege the base term is an agreement on what product can be offered at the lowest price point offered by SLPTV providers. CAC ¶ 316. On its face, Disney's base term requirement does not appear to lack any redeeming value such that it warrants per se treatment.

For example, vertical agreements that facilitate horizontal collusion and "[v]ertical agreements that foreclose competitors from entering or competing in a market can injure competition by reducing the competitive threat those competitors would pose." Brantley, 675 F.3d at 1198.

Accordingly, Plaintiffs have failed to establish a per se horizontal agreement between competitors to restrain trade.

2. Plaintiffs allege a vertical restraint in violation of the Rule of Reason

As an alternative to its claim of a per se violation of Section 1, Plaintiffs also allege a claim under the rule of reason. CAC ¶ 365.

To establish a rule of reason violation a plaintiff must plead "(1) a contract, combination or conspiracy among two or more persons or distinct business entities; (2) by which the persons or entities intended to harm or restrain trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations; (3) which actually injures competition." Brantley, 675 F.3d at 1197.

Before the court can apply the rule of reason, the court must consider the relevant market. Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 585 U.S. 529, 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2285, 201 L.Ed.2d 678 (2018). A plausible relevant market must include a geographic and a product market. Hicks v. PGA Tour, Inc., 897 F.3d 1109, 1120 (9th Cir. 2018). An alleged relevant market can survive a motion to dismiss "unless it is apparent from the face of the complaint that the alleged market suffers a fatal legal defect." Newcal Indus., Inc. v. Ikon Off. Sol., 513 F.3d 1038, 1045 (9th Cir. 2008).

a. Relevant market in which Disney has Market Power

First, Disney contends Plaintiffs fail at the threshold inquiry by failing to allege the proper relevant market. MTD at 12.

To plead § 1 of the Sherman Act, a plaintiff "must allege both that a 'relevant market' exists and that the defendant has power within that market." Newcal Indus., Inc. v. Ikon Office Sol., 513 F.3d 1038, 1044 (9th Cir. 2008). The relevant market is defined as "the area of effective competition." Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Qualcomm Inc., 969 F.3d 974, 992 (9th Cir. 2020) (quotations and citation omitted). There are two components to a relevant market: the geographic market and the product market. Thurman Indus., Inc. v. Pay 'N Pak Stores, Inc., 875 F.2d 1369, 1373 (9th Cir. 1989).

A product market "must encompass the product at issue as well as all economic substitutes for the product." Newcal Indus., 513 F.3d at 1045. "The outer boundaries of a product market are determined by the reasonable interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand between the product itself and substitutes for it." Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962). Well-defined submarkets may constitute product markets for antitrust purposes. Id.; Thurman Indus., Inc. v. Pay 'N Pak Stores, Inc., 875 F.2d 1369, 1374 (9th Cir. 1989) ("In limited settings . . . the relevant product market may be narrowed beyond the boundaries of physical interchangeability and cross-price elasticity to account for identifiable submarkets or product clusters."). To plead a relevant submarket, a plaintiff must plausibly allege "that the alleged submarket is economically distinct from the general product market." Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1045. Whether a submarket is economically distinct is determined by "examining such practical indicia", including: (1) industry or public recognition of the submarket, (2) peculiar characteristics and uses of the product, (3) unique production facilities, (4) distinct customers, (5) distinct prices, (6) sensitivity to price changes, and (7) specialized vendors. Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 325, 82 S.Ct. 1502 (1962). "At bottom, economic distinction depends on whether the purported submarket is meaningfully insulated [ ] from competition with other products in the broader market." In re German Auto. Mfrs. Antitrust Litig., 497 F. Supp. 3d 745, 756 (N.D. Cal. 2020), aff'd, No. 20-17139, 2021 WL 4958987 (9th Cir. Oct. 26, 2021) (quotations and citation omitted).

Plaintiffs define the relevant product and geographic market as the SLPTV market in the United States. CAC ¶¶ 223, 278. The SLPTV market is a submarket of the broader LPTV market, which includes providers of cable and satellite television. Id. SLPTV is a subscription-based service provided by Virtual Multichannel Video Programming Distributors ("vMVPDs"). Id. ¶ 223. In the SLPTV market, SLPTV providers, or vMVPDs, sell "subscription-based services that provide access to live television channels over a broadband internet connection" via channel packages or bundles. Id. ¶ 224. vMVPDs provide a "base" package level to SLPTV subscribers which contains the minimum number of channels of all the package tiers. Id. ¶ 225.

To the extent Disney challenges the relevant market, the parties do not appear to dispute the geographic market. See CAC ¶¶ 275-83.

Plaintiffs allege the industry and public recognize the SLPTV submarket as a "separate economic entity" from the LPTV market. Id. ¶ 229. Industry participants distinguish the differences in how SLPTV delivers video content. Id. ¶ 230-33. For example, SLPTV products are more flexible than traditional LPTV products because they do not require separate transmission infrastructure or technology such as cable boxes or a satellite dish. Id. ¶¶ 235-49, 242. Instead, SLPTV products rely on existing broadband internet connections, which enables SLPTV subscribers to use laptops, PC, game consoles, smart TVs, tablets, and smartphones to stream live TV channels without needing to connect to additional hardware. Id. ¶¶ 239-40. The SLPTV market also has distinct customers from the LPTV market, which tend to skew younger—with around 91% of 18-to 29-year-olds in the U.S. participating in the market—and tend to consume less video using cable television. Id. ¶¶ 259-61. Not only do younger viewers prefer live stream television, but many also prefer to watch using hand-held devices. Id. ¶ 261. Finally, the SLPTV bundles have historically included fewer channels than LPTV bundles and therefore typically cost less and the SLPTV market is not as sensitive to price changes as traditional cable. Id. ¶¶ 266, 268.

Disney argues, however, that the SLPTV market is downstream from where the alleged restraint occurs. As the Ninth Circuit observed, "[t]he television programming industry can be divided into upstream and downstream markets." Brantley, 675 F.3d at 1195. The "upstream market" is composed of television programmers that own television channels and the "downstream market" is where distributors sell the channels to consumers. Id. According to Disney, the correct market is upstream, or where ESPN and vMVPD negotiations occur since that is where the carriage agreements are being negotiated, i.e., where competition is being restrained. MTD at 12. Plaintiffs contend, however, the proper market "is the market in which Plaintiffs purchased the price-inflated product—the SLPTV product—because the relevant consumer for market definition purposes is the SLPTV subscriber, not Disney's SLPTV competitors that entered into unlawful agreements with it." Opp'n to MTD at 18.

Disney also argues in a footnote that the relevant market is facially defective because the CAC suggests traditional MVPDs are substitutes for vMVPDs (the SLPTV submarket). MTD at 13 n.3; see CAC ¶¶ 112, 133, 231, 233, 262-63. The Court is not persuaded that the MVPD market is an economic substitute that has "actual or potential ability to deprive" vMPVDs of "significant levels of business." Thurman Indus., Inc. v. Pay 'N Pak Stores, Inc., 875 F.2d 1369, 1374 (9th Cir. 1989). Such a question is better resolved at the summary judgment stage. See e.g., Datel Holdings Ltd. v. Microsoft Corp., 712 F. Supp. 2d 974, 997 (N.D. Cal. 2010); In re Webkinz Antitrust Litig., 695 F. Supp. 2d 987, 995 (N.D. Cal. 2010).

As a threshold matter, the Court observes that the existence of a relevant market and whether a defendant has power within that market are typically factual inquiries for the trier of fact. Newcal Indus., Inc. v. Ikon Office Sol., 513 F.3d 1038, 1045 (9th Cir. 2008). Allegations of a relevant market and market power generally pass the test at the pleading stage unless the market definition is "facially unsustainable." Id.

When assessing the relevant market, courts must focus on anticompetitive effects "in the market where competition is [allegedly] being restrained." Qualcomm Inc., 969 F.3d at 992 (alteration in original) (quoting Am. Ad Mgmt., Inc. v. Gen. Tel. Co. of Cal., 190 F.3d 1051, 1057 (9th Cir. 1999)). Plaintiffs allege that competition is harmed in the SLPTV market. CAC ¶¶ 304-05, 365. Television programmers sell channels to SLPTV providers (or vMVPDs), and SLPTV providers are harmed by the anticompetitive terms in the carriage agreements, which have caused prices for SLPTV subscriptions to nearly double and have limited consumer choice. Id. ¶ 365-66. Thus, competition is allegedly being unreasonably restrained in the SLPTV market. The Court finds this product market definition adequate at this stage given Plaintiffs' theory of harm. See Brantley v. NBC Universal, Inc., No. 07-CV-6101CASVBKX, 2008 WL 11357958, at *3 n.2 (C.D. Cal. June 25, 2008) ("That the restrained market is upstream from the consumer plaintiffs may make standing more difficult to establish, but it does not, in and of itself, render the product market definition insufficient.").

In addition to defining a relevant market, a plaintiff must plead "that the defendant has power within that market." Newcal Indus., Inc., 513 F.3d at 1045. "Market power" under § 1 refers to "the ability to raise prices above those that would be charged in a competitive market." NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of the Univ. of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 109 n.38, 104 S.Ct. 2948, 82 L.Ed.2d 70 (1984). Direct evidence of market power includes a showing of restricted output and supracompetitive prices. Theme Promotions, Inc. v. News Am. Mktg. FSI, 546 F.3d 991, 1001 (9th Cir. 2008). Indirect or circumstantial evidence requires the plaintiff to "(1) define the relevant market, (2) show that the defendant owns a dominant share of that market, and (3) show that there are significant barriers to entry and . . . that existing competitors lack the capacity to increase their output in the short run." Rebel Oil Co, Inc. v. Atlantic Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1434 (9th Cir. 1995).

The allegations rely on Disney's ownership interests in ESPN (i.e., the ESPN Network) and Hulu and the carriage agreements, which vests Disney with market power. For example, the CAC alleges that Disney has "pricing power over the entire market" based on ESPN's carriage agreements with all leading SLPTV market competitors. CAC ¶¶ 3-5. Disney's control of the second largest SLPTV provider, Hulu, and its control of the "largest input into every SLPTV product in the country," ESPN, in combination with the base term and MFN clauses in the ESPN carriage agreements enable Disney to impose inflated costs on competitors and set a price floor. Id. The Court likewise finds that these allegations are sufficient at the pleading stage. See Brantley, 2008 WL 11357958, at *3 (holding plaintiffs sufficiently alleged market power where the complaint alleged that each of the programmer defendants maintains market power by virtue of its ownership of key broadcast networks or cable channels).

In sum, Plaintiffs have adequately alleged a relevant market in which Disney has market power for Rule 12(b)(6) purposes.

b. Agreements that unreasonably restrain trade

Finally, Disney maintains Plaintiffs have failed to plead the existence of vertical agreements that could be unreasonable restraints of trade under the rule of reason. To state a rule of reason claim, a plaintiff must show in factual detail "an injury to competition, rather than just an injury to plaintiff's business." Sicor, Ltd. v. Cetus Corp., 51 F.3d 848, 854 (9th Cir. 1995).

Plaintiffs allege that the base term and MFN clause unreasonably restrains trade. The base term requirements allow Disney direct input into competitor pricing and the MFN clause allows Disney to set the lowest price available for ESPN across the entire market because (i) Disney owns Hulu + Live TV, which enables Disney to set a minimum price, and (ii) "there is no competitive ESPN-less product" in the market. CAC ¶¶ 315-16, 364. This means that ESPN affiliate fees negotiated with any given cable operator represent an "industrywide price floor." Id. ¶¶ 55, 315. For example, if prices for ESPN increased, Disney's agreements with other providers ensured that cable package prices would all increase lockstep. Id. ¶ 57. Conversely, "if Disney lowers the cost of Hulu + Live TV by 10%, the MFN price term requires that other provider-competitors receive the same price." Id. ¶ 317. However, Disney would not be motivated to do so "since any discount to one cable or satellite provider would mean providing a market-wide discount to all other counterparties." Id. ¶ 57. Thus, it operates as a price floor and exerts upward pressure on prices. Id. ¶ 364.

Plaintiffs allege that Disney Entity's agreements ensure pricing parity or increasing prices without a "competitive check." Id. ¶¶ 57-58. According to Plaintiffs, ESPN cost increases affect competitors but are "illusory" or a "mere accounting fictions" as to Hulu + Live TV. Id. ¶ 320. In other words, because Disney controls both ESPN and Hulu, Disney can impose ESPN affiliate fees on SLPTV providers without meaningfully increasing costs for its own SLPTV product, Hulu + Live TV. Id. ¶ 362. As Disney increases the cost of ESPN fees, the cost of the cheapest bundles also increases. Id. ¶ 324. Plaintiffs allege that there are no procompetitive benefits to forcing customers to subscribe to ESPN as part of base packages. Id. ¶ 337.

Disney does not allege the base term or MFN clause have procompetitive advantages, but Disney challenges whether MFN clauses can harm competition. MTD at 16-18. As previously noted, MFN clauses can be used for anticompetitive ends. See, e.g., In re Elec. Books, 859 F. Supp. 2d 671; United States v. Delta Dental of Rhode Island, 943 F. Supp. 172 (D.R.I. 1996) (discussing anticompetitive effects of MFN clauses); Willamette Dental Group, P.C. v. Oregon Dental Serv. Corp., 130 Or.App. 487, 496, 882 P.2d 637 (1994) ("We note, moreover, the possibility that, is some circumstances, the enforcement of most favored nations clauses can have severe anticompetitive effects.").

Disney challenges whether the base term and MFN clause unreasonably restrain trade. MTD at 14-18. Relying on the Ninth Circuit opinion in Brantley, Disney contends that allegations of reduced consumer choice and preventing SLPTV providers from offering cheaper "skinny bundles" without the ESPN Network are insufficient to allege an injury to competition. MTD at 14-15 (citing Brantley, 675 F.3d 1192).

The facts of Brantley are not dissimilar to this action. In Brantley, consumers of television programming brought an antitrust suit against several owners of television channels that are distributed through cable, as well as several owners of cable distributors, alleging that defendants conspired to restrain trade in violation of § 1. See Brantley v. NBC Universal, Inc., No. 07-CV-6101CASVBKX, 2009 WL 10671189 (C.D. Cal. Oct. 15, 2009). The television "Programmer Defendants", such as NBC Universal, owned television channels sold to cable distributors such as Time Warner. Brantley, 675 F.3d at 1195. The Programmer Defendants and cable distributors entered into vertical agreements with "bundling arrangements" which required distributors to purchase and sell all NBC Universal's channels as a multi-channel package, rather than permitting distributors from selling each channel separately. Id. at 1195-96. Plaintiffs alleged that the "Programmers' practice of selling packaged cable channels foreclosed independent programmers from entering and competing in the upstream market for programming channels." Id. at 1196. The district court concluded that plaintiffs had adequately alleged injury to competition. Id. However, plaintiffs later amended the complaint to delete the allegation that the programmer Defendants' practices with the distributors foreclose independent programmers from participating in the upstream market, leaving only allegations of reduced consumer choice and increased prices. Id. The district court subsequently dismissed plaintiffs' complaint for failure to allege a cognizable injury. Id.

The Programmer Defendants included NBC Universal, Inc., Viacom, Inc., The Walt Disney Company, Fox Entertainment Group, Inc., and Turner Broadcasting Systems, Inc. Brantley v. NBC Universal, Inc., 2009 WL 10671189, at *1 n.1.

The Court agrees with Disney that, to the extent Plaintiffs rely on allegations of reduced consumer choice and increased subscription prices, these allegations are insufficient to allege an injury to competition. Brantley, 675 F.3d at 1202. Indeed, the Ninth Circuit concluded that "because Section 1 does not proscribe all contracts that limit the freedom of the contracting parties, a statement that parties have entered into a contract that limits some freedom of action (in this case, by circumscribing the distributors' ability to offer smaller packages or channels on an unbundled basis) is not sufficient to allege an injury to competition." Id. The fact that the base term and MFN clause harms consumers does not state a cognizable injury to competition.

In Brantley, plaintiffs' allegations consisted of two separate tying arrangements: a tying arrangement in the upstream market where NBC Universal requires each cable distributor to who wishes to purchase its high demand channels must also purchase its low demand channels; and a second tying arrangement in the downstream market where distributors sell consumers cable channels only in packages consisting of the NBC Universal's entire offering of channels. Id. at 1200-01. While tying arrangements do not, on their own, threaten injury to competition, the Ninth Circuit enumerated multiple types of injuries the plaintiffs could allege, including that: (1) the seller's practice excludes other sellers from the market; (2) the seller's practice raises barriers to entry; and (3) the tying arrangement facilitates horizontal collusion. Id. at 1201.

Here, unlike in Brantley, Plaintiffs also allege that, in addition to increased prices, the infrastructure and agreements have produced barriers to entry. CAC ¶ 287. Detailed allegations of barriers to entry are sufficient to allege anticompetitive harm. Cf. Orchard Supply Hardware LLC v. Home Depot USA, Inc., 967 F. Supp. 2d 1347, 1358 (N.D. Cal. 2013) (finding generic allegations insufficient to plead a viable injury to competition, noting, inter alia, that there were no allegations that the agreement facilitated horizontal collusion or foreclosed competitors from entering into or competing in a market.). For example, Plaintiffs describe a Carriage and Streaming Infrastructure Barrier to Entry ("CSIBE") which requires expensive servers with significant computing power that are capable of processing high resolution video and with minimal latency and sufficient bandwidth to deliver video content over the internet. Id. ¶¶ 288-90. The CAC alleges that "[t]o credibly enter the SLPTV market, a company must traverse the CSIBE not only by obtaining computing power, distributed computing systems, large amounts of data storage, and local data servers, but also by developing custom file systems and software infrastructure to optimize streams." Id. ¶ 293. Companies such as YouTube had existing streaming video structure that enabled it to quickly enter the SLPTV market at scale. Id. ¶ 294. Without pre-existing streaming infrastructure, new entrants will have to acquire the necessary computing power and at storage to meet the baseline criteria to compete across the U.S. (i.e., low latency, high resolution, and robust streaming). Id. ¶ 295. Plaintiffs allege that this infrastructure is cost-prohibitive to build from scratch. Id. ¶ 296. Indeed, Disney was able to quickly enter the SLPTV market because it uses Amazon Web Services for its streaming services, Hulu's pre-existing streaming infrastructure. Id. ¶ 297.

Moreover, Plaintiffs allege that successful entry into the SLPTV market also requires entering into multiple carriage agreements with cable providers to secure a "critical mass" of television channels. Id. ¶ 299. Securing these agreements are slow and costly. Id. Not only must market entrants negotiate with large cable providers such as Disney and NBC Universal, new entrants also must secure local television channels, which are controlled "by a confusing, difficult-to-navigate web of companies, with complicated (and occasionally divided) carriage and/or transmission rights that must be acquired." Id. ¶ 300. Failure to secure enough channels "renders a platform inviable as an SLPTV platform." Id.

In sum, in addition to alleging reduced consumer choice and increased prices, Plaintiffs allege that Disney's anticompetitive conduct has increased prices and strengthened the CSIBE to prevent entry by potential rival because a new entrant would need to contract with Disney in order to obtain "several notable channels," such as ESPN, that are on every SLPTV platform. Id. ¶ 301. "Disney thus maintains a cost input into each market participant's product, and can prevent or retard entry by mandating onerous terms or by outright refusing to license live television content." Id. ¶ 303.

Taken as true, these allegations are sufficient at the pleading stage to state an injury to competition in violation of Sherman Act § 1.

B. Claims for Damages

Finally, Disney argues Plaintiffs are barred from seeking damages by Illinois Brick because they are indirect purchasers. MTD at 19. In Illinois Brick, the Supreme Court held that "Indirect purchasers—i.e., individuals purchasing a product from at a point in the supply chain removed from the antitrust violation—generally have no standing under Section 4 of the Clayton Act." Brantley v. NBC Universal, Inc., 2008 WL 11338585, at *5 (C.D.Cal. Mar. 10, 2008) (citing Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720, 728-29, 97 S.Ct. 2061, 52 L.Ed.2d 707 (1977)). There is an exception to this rule for co-conspirators. See State of Ariz. v. Shamrock Foods Co., 729 F.2d 1208, 1211 (9th Cir. 1984).

According to Plaintiffs, Disney mischaracterizes Plaintiffs as indirect purchasers rather than as "direct purchasers of SLPTV subscriptions from DirecTV Stream" as pled. Opp'n to MTD at 25. Because Plaintiffs allege that Disney conspired with DirecTV Stream, its "fiercest competitor", Plaintiffs contend that the co-conspirator exception applies. Id. (citing CAC ¶¶ 151-63, 174-93, 213-19, 301-24, 353-61). The Court disagrees. The co-conspirator exception applies only to conspiracies among horizontal competitors to fix prices. See State of Ariz., 729 F.2d at 1211. Because the Court has determined that Plaintiffs fail to allege a horizontal agreement between competitors to restrain trade, this exception is not available to Plaintiffs. See supra Section III.A.1. Pursuant to Illinois Brick, indirect purchasers in a chain of distribution cannot sue for damages "based on unlawful overcharges passed onto them by intermediaries in the distribution chain who purchased directly from the alleged antitrust violator." Id. at 1211-12.

Accordingly, Plaintiffs cannot maintain their claim for damages.

C. Leave to Amend

Plaintiffs request leave to amend any pleading deficiencies. "Requests for leave to amend should be granted with 'extreme liberality.' " Brown v. Stored Value Cards, Inc., 953 F.3d 567, 574 (9th Cir. 2020). A court should not grant leave to amend if "it determines that the pleading could not possibly be cured by allegation of other facts." Cook, Perkiss and Liehe, Inc. v. N. Cal. Collection Serv. Inc., 911 F.2d 242, 247 (9th Cir. 1990). The Court cannot say that Plaintiffs are unable to allege facts establishing the existence of Sherman Act § 1 per se violation at this time. Therefore, Plaintiffs' request is GRANTED.

IV. CONCLUSION

For the foregoing reasons, Defendant's motion to dismiss for failure to state a claim is GRANTED IN PART and DENIED IN PART with leave to amend. The Court DENIES Disney's motion to dismiss Plaintiffs' claim that Disney violated the Sherman Act § 1 under the rule of reason and GRANTS Disney's motion to dismiss Plaintiffs' claim that Disney per se violated the Sherman Act § 1 and for damages. Should Plaintiffs choose to file an amended complaint, they must do so by October 16, 2023. Plaintiffs may not add new claims or parties without leave of the Court or stipulation by the parties pursuant to Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 15.

In light of the Court's ruling on the motion to dismiss, Defendant's motion to stay discovery pending resolution of the motion to dismiss at ECF No. 43 is TERMINATED AS MOOT.

IT IS SO ORDERED.


Summaries of

Biddle v. The Walt Disney Co.

United States District Court, Northern District of California
Sep 29, 2023
696 F. Supp. 3d 865 (N.D. Cal. 2023)
Case details for

Biddle v. The Walt Disney Co.

Case Details

Full title:HEATHER BIDDLE, et al., Plaintiffs, v. THE WALT DISNEY COMPANY, Defendant.

Court:United States District Court, Northern District of California

Date published: Sep 29, 2023

Citations

696 F. Supp. 3d 865 (N.D. Cal. 2023)